Project Gutenberg's Royal Railways with Uniform Rates, by Whately C. Arnold This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License included with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you are not located in the United States, you'll have to check the laws of the country where you are located before using this ebook. Title: Royal Railways with Uniform Rates A proposal for amalgamation of Railways with the General Post Office and adoption of uniform fares and rates for any distance Author: Whately C. Arnold Release Date: October 6, 2016 [EBook #53222] Language: English Character set encoding: UTF-8 *** START OF THIS PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK ROYAL RAILWAYS WITH UNIFORM RATES *** Produced by MWS, Adrian Mastronardi, The Philatelic Digital Library Project at http://www.tpdlp.net and the Online Distributed Proofreading Team at http://www.pgdp.net (This file was produced from images generously made available by The Internet Archive/American Libraries.) A RAILWAY REVOLUTION! [Illustration] ROYAL RAILWAYS FARES & RATES FOR ANY DISTANCE. LOCAL TRAINS ONE PENNY MAIN LINE ” ONE SHILLING SLOW GOODS average } 1s. 6d. FAST ” per ton } 10s. A business proposition for Shareholders and the Nation. _Sixpence Nett._ SIMPKIN, MARSHALL, HAMILTON, KENT & CO., LTD., LONDON ROYAL RAILWAYS with Uniform Rates _by_ WHATELY C. ARNOLD, LL.B. LOND. _A PROPOSAL for amalgamation of Railways with the General Post Office and adoption of uniform fares and rates for any distance._ LONDON: SIMPKIN, MARSHALL, HAMILTON, KENT & CO., LTD 1914 _Preface._ This pamphlet has been printed and published with the assistance of friends who share my opinion that the scheme proposed will solve the railway problem--now at an acute stage. A rough outline of the Scheme has been submitted to Sir Charles Cameron, Bart. (on whose initiative sixpenny telegrams were adopted), and while reserving his opinion as to the advantages of State ownership and the difficulties of purchase, he has been good enough to write that this scheme is the boldest and best reasoned plea for the Nationalisation of Railways that he has come across. The scheme has also been submitted to, among others, Mr. Emil Davies, Chairman of the Railway Nationalisation Society, to Mr. L. G. Chiozza Money, M.P., and to Mr. Philip Snowden, M.P., all of whom have expressed their approval subject to the figures and estimates being correct. These figures and estimates are based on the Official Board of Trade returns for Railways of 1911 and 1912. I also had the temerity to submit my draft to Mr. W. M. Acworth, the well-known Railway expert, who very courteously gave me his views generally, although refraining from any detailed criticism. I deal with his remarks at the end of Chapter IV., but may here mention that Mr. Acworth called my attention to an article by himself on Railways in “Palgrave’s Encyclopædia of Political Economy” published in 1899. In such article he referred to a suggestion which had then been made for uniform fares on the Postal system, and he dismissed the idea in a sentence as impracticable, because no one would pay for a short journey as much as 8d., then the average fare for the whole country. It is therefore evident that the principle of a flat rate is not novel; yet I can find no reference in any books or pamphlets on railways to any practical scheme for carrying it into effect. Apparently it has been assumed that there can be only one uniform rate, equivalent to the average rate, and that therefore the proposal is quite impossible. The simple expedient of dividing the traffic into the two kinds of “Fast” and “Slow,” on the analogy of the Postal rate of one penny for letters and sixpence for telegrams, overcomes this difficulty. The scheme is in effect an extension to the Railway System of the principle upon which the existing Postal System is founded, and therefore involves Nationalisation. As submitted to the above-named gentlemen, the draft did not include my remarks on the principles which in my opinion should govern all National and Municipal Trading, and which are now contained in Chapter IV. The attention of both opponents and advocates of Nationalisation is particularly called to these principles, which I have not found elsewhere, but which as laid down are believed to be absolutely sound, and of the highest importance, as removing most, if not all, of the objections of opponents, while retaining all the advantages claimed by advocates of National and Municipal Trading. I do not pretend to be a railway expert, and have only been able to devote the small leisure time available from an exacting business to putting into writing the thoughts which have exercised my mind for many years past. But the well-known expert, Mr. Edwin A. Pratt, who is a strong opponent of Railway Nationalisation, admits in one of his books that “the greatest advances made by the Post Office have been due to the persistence of outside and far-seeing reformers, rather than to the Postal Officials themselves.” This admission and the conviction that the further advance now proposed is based upon sound principles and undisputed facts, encourages me to submit my scheme with confidence to the consideration of experts and the public. W. C. A. 37, NORFOLK STREET, STRAND, LONDON, W.C. DECEMBER, 1913. SYNOPSIS OF CONTENTS PROPOSED UNIFORM FARES AND RATES: =Passenger Fares=: Any Distance, so far as train travels. _Main Lines_: =First Class 5/-=, =Third Class 1/-=. _Local Lines_: ” =6d.= ” =1d.= =Goods Rates=: Any Distance. _Fast Service_: =Average 10/- per ton=. _Slow Service_: ” =1/6= ” =Introduction.= Page 15. The Royal Mail.--Letters carried for same price any distance. Why not passengers and goods? Object of pamphlet to prove that this is financially possible with small uniform fares and rates mentioned. A Business Proposition for Nation and Shareholders. CHAPTER I. =The Scheme.= Page 17. =All Railways= to be purchased by State and amalgamated with General Post Office. Trains of two kinds only, viz.:-- (1) =Main Line Trains=, _i.e._, non-stop for at least 30 miles. (2) =Local Trains=, _i.e._, all trains other than Main Line. =Passenger tickets= vary according to above fares only--no reference to stations or distance. =Goods rates=, payable by stamps vary only according to weight or size of goods, whether carried in bulk, in open or closed trucks, or with special packing, but irrespective of any other difference in nature or value of goods, or of distance, as now with parcel post. =All Railway Stations to be Post Offices.= All Post Offices to sell Railway Tickets, and, where required, to be Railway Receiving Offices. =Steamers= to be regarded as trains. CHAPTER II. =Advantages of Scheme.= Page 20. 1. =Cheapness= and regularity of transport. 2. =Economy= of service;--by unification of railways;--abolition of Railway Clearing House, of expenses of varying rates and fares, of multiplication of receiving offices, stations, &c.,--and by amalgamation with Post Office;--all railway land and buildings available for Government purposes--Postal, Civil, Military and Naval. 3. =Progressive increase always follows= adoption of small uniform fares (_e.g._, in Post Office); hence progressive increase of revenue available for working expenses, purchase money, extensions, improvements, and adoption of new safety appliances. CHAPTER III. =Principles of Scheme.= Page 27. =Present system= founded on two principles, both mistaken and illogical, viz.:--(=1=) According to distance travelled. (=2=) According to “what the traffic will bear.” (1) Although cost of building 200 miles, and hauling train that distance is more than for two miles, yet because regular train service required for whole distance, say, A to Z and back, passing intermediate places, therefore cost of travelling from A to B, or to N, identical with A to Z. For goods, cost of loading and unloading twice only, whether sent from A to B, or A to Z. (2) Cost of hauling ton of coal exactly same as of bricks, sand, loaded van, in open truck, yet now different rates for each, according to “what the traffic will bear.” =True principle= advocated by Sir Rowland Hill in Penny Post--whole country suffers by neglect or expense of transport to distant parts, and gains by including small districts with same rates as populous parts. =For a flat rate, three rules necessary.= (_a_) Must not exceed lowest in use prior to adoption. (_b_) Increased traffic resulting must produce at least same net revenue. (_c_) Variations of rate to be according to speed, not distance. Hence: (_a_) =1d.= now lowest fare, fixed for Local Lines. =1s.= now lowest fare, (_e.g._, 2s. 6d. return London to Brighton) fixed for Main Lines. =1s. 6d.= per ton fixed for goods train or slow service, as the present average for minerals, and allowing present lowest rate for goods in open trucks, rising to, say, 6d. per cwt. (10s. per ton) for small consignments, in covered trucks. =10s.= per ton, now lowest “per passenger train” (_e.g._, 6d. per cwt. for returned empties) fixed for fast service. (_b_) The increased traffic dealt with under “Finance.” (_c_) The two rates suggested for fast and slow trains solve the difficulty hitherto felt of charging lowest fare of 1d. as uniform fare--the 1s. fare and 10s. goods rate being double the present averages. CHAPTER IV. =OBJECTIONS TO THE SCHEME.= =1.--State Ownership.= Page 33. Writers for and against--All assume that on Nationalisation, system followed of charging according to distance, and to “what traffic will bear”--Fundamental differences between State Monopoly and Private Monopoly--Evils of applying profits of State monopolies in reductions of taxation--Strikes. Four rules to be observed on Nationalisation:-- 1. Natural monopolies only to be taken over. 2. When taken over, only to be worked for benefit of community and not for profit. 3. Competition of private enterprises not to be prohibited. 4. Monopoly to be worked by Department of State responsible to Parliament. =Chief grounds of objection to State ownership=-- (1) Difficulty of Government in dealing with conflicting interests of traders and general public. (2) Difficulty of Railway servants (being also voters) using political pressure to obtain better wages, against interests of traders and general public. Both of these objections removed if scheme (which avoids all preferential or differential rates or treatment) adopted with above four rules. Other grounds of objection, _e.g._, want of competition, officialism, &c., apply equally to present Company system, but may be remedied if owned by State. Suggested remedies:--Railway Council to deal with all matters of administration; Railway Courts to deal with questions of compensation, labour disputes, &c. Railways and Post Office being Department of State with Cabinet Minister at head subject to vote of censure in Parliament, provides better security for public than private Companies or Railway Trust. =2.--General Objections.= Page 43. =Fear of Losses=-- All existing staffs required for increased traffic--therefore no loss to them. Traders, like newspapers more than make up for any losses by economy in rates and fares and increased circulation. Mr. Acworth’s objections to “average” rates considered. CHAPTER V. =Finance of Scheme.= Page 45. =Present averages= per annum in round figures taken from Board of Trade returns 1911 and 1912:-- Receipts from Passengers £45,000,000 ” ” Goods per passenger train 10,000,000 ” ” Goods Train Traffic 64,000,000 ” (Miscellaneous) 10,000,000 -------------- Gross Revenue £129,000,000 Working Expenses 81,000,000 -------------- Net Receipts £48,000,000 ============== Total Paid-up Capital and Debentures £1,400,000,000 Net receipts show average income of 3½ per cent. * * * * * Total passenger journeys (of which 10 per cent. were 1st and 2nd class) 1,620,000,000 =Average fare for each journey only 6½d.= * * * * * Total tonnage of goods:-- Estimate per passenger trains 20,000,000 Actual per goods trains 524,000,000 ------------ 544,000,000 * * * * * Average rates per goods train:-- Minerals only 1s. 6d. per ton General Merchandise 6s. ” Both together 2s. 4d. ” =Estimate under proposed scheme=:-- Page 48. =I. Passengers.=--Assuming Main Line passenger journeys are 300,000,000, _i.e._, under 20 per cent. of the total passenger journeys. 300,000,000 at 1s. = £15,000,000 add 30,000,000 at 4s. for 1st class = 6,000,000 1,320,000,000 at 1d. = 5,500,000 add 132,000,000 at 5d. for 1st class = 2,750,000 ------------- ----------- Present No. 1,620,000,000 will produce £29,250,000 Increased number of Main Line passengers required to make up deficiency:-- 250,000,000 at 1s £12,500,000 add 25,000,000 at 4s. extra 5,000,000 ---------- £17,500,000 ----------- Estimated total £46,750,000 This is £1,750,000 more than the present gross revenue from passengers and requires an increase of 250,000,000 = 15 per cent. on the total present number of passenger journeys. =II. Goods.= Total tonnage by goods train as now, viz., 524,000,000, at 1s. 6d £39,300,000 Ditto per passenger train, 20,000,000 at 10s 10,000,000 Live Stock, as now 1,500,000 ----------- £50,800,000 Increased tonnage required to make up present revenue, 48,000,000 tons at 10s. 24,000,000 ----------- £74,800,000 =========== which is £800,000 more than present total receipts from goods per passenger and goods trains, and requires an increase of under 10 per cent. in tonnage. =Reasons for anticipating increase=:-- =(_a_) Of Passengers.= Long distance journeys now restricted by expense.--Through tickets now counted as one journey will, under new scheme, be sometimes two or three, _e.g._, London to Londonderry would be three tickets--Every single journey taken, usually means also return journey home. =(_b_) Of Goods.= Example of Post Office--Before Penny Post, average price per letter 7d., and letters carried 76,000,000. After Penny Post, first year number doubled; in twenty years, increased by eight times; about doubled every twenty years since. Before three letters per head of population, now 72 per head. Goods now sent by road motors will, with cheaper rates, go by rail--perishable articles, now not sent at all by fast train owing to expense, will be sent when rates cheaper. CHAPTER VI. =Working Expenses.= Page 53. =If increase= of traffic no more than above, increase of working expenses negligible, apart from economies made by unification. Expense of carrying 200 passengers no more than 20. If increase of traffic more, then revenue increases, but working expenses only by about 50 per cent., as expenses of permanent way, stations, signal boxes, and establishment charges but little affected. Expenses of Post Office and Railways to be lumped together. CHAPTER VII. =Terms of Purchase.= Page 56. =Present total market price= of all Railway Stock and shares about £1,350,000,000 Debentures and Loans ” 350,000,000 -------------- Total about £1,700,000,000 =Estimate of annual sum= required according to precedent of purchase of the East Indian Railway Company, namely, by annuities for 73 years, equal to 4¼ per cent. per annum on market value, plus liability for Loans and Debentures with interest at 3 per cent. 4¼ per cent. on £1,350,000,000 £57,375,000 3 ” ” 350,000,000 10,800,000 ----------- Total annual sum required for purchase £68,175,000 =Revenue available as per= above estimates:-- Passengers £46,750,000 Goods 74,800,000 Miscellaneous, as now 10,000,000 ------------ £131,550,000 Less Working Expenses, with say, increase of £4,000,000 85,000,000 ------------ Net revenue available £46,550,000 ----------- Balance required for purchase £21,625,000 would be provided by following further increase of traffic, viz. 100,000,000 passengers at 1s. £5,000,000 10,000,000 ” ” 4s. 2,000,000 30,000,000 tons ” 10s. 15,000,000 ----------- £22,000,000 =========== This further traffic brings total increase of traffic to:-- 350,000,000 passengers = about 21 per cent. 78,000,000 tons of goods = about 15 per cent. Essential to purchase all Railways at same date--Railway Stock to be converted into Government Stock--Price to be fixed by average of market price of Stocks for three years prior to introduction of Bill. CHAPTER VIII. =Conclusion.= Page 62. Interested parties not prejudiced--Staff now employed in services to be discarded will be required for increased traffic--Facility of transport will increase trade, and open new markets, not only here but abroad--Foreign countries would adopt reform as they did Postal system--Advantages of inter-communication with Foreign Nations. ROYAL RAILWAYS with Uniform Rates. INTRODUCTION. =The Royal Mail!= What scenes and memories are conjured up by these words! In the olden days, the Royal Mail coaches--in these modern days, the well-known scarlet Mail carts and motor vans arriving at all the larger railway stations from which the mail trains, always the fastest, convey the mails to every quarter of the United Kingdom, and over the whole world. It is now a commonplace to post in the nearest pillar-box a batch of letters, some to addresses in the same town, others to provincial towns and villages, to Scotland, Ireland and far distant Colonies, each of them being conveyed to their destination, near or far, for the modest sum of one penny, by the speediest mode of locomotion that steam and electricity can provide. In order that travellers may have the advantage of that speed and regularity which is a feature of the Royal Mail, passengers and goods have always been carried by the Mail--formerly by the coach, now by the train. But whereas the mails are carried at the same price for any distance, the charges for passengers, and for goods which exceed the regulation size and weight permitted for the “Parcels Post,” vary according to the distance travelled, and as to goods also according to their nature or quality, with the result that for the greater part of our population long journeys are luxuries which can only be undertaken in cases of life and death, and not always then; the rates for carriage of goods by fast train are mostly prohibitive, and even by goods train for long distances are so great as to seriously restrict the traffic. If mail trains can carry mails, with parcels up to 7 lbs. in weight at the same price for any distance, why cannot all trains carry passengers and goods of any size and weight at the same price for any distance? The answer is that they can, and it is the object of this pamphlet to prove not only that it is possible financially, but that, with the small uniform fares and rates indicated on the title page, sufficient revenue can be obtained to pay working expenses, and provide the sum required to purchase the whole of the existing railway undertakings at their full market price, or such a price as willing vendors would be ready to accept. This, then, is “=A Business Proposition=” for all concerned; in other words, the magnificent net-work of railways in the United Kingdom, with all that is included in their undertakings, may be acquired by the nation at such a price as will make it worth the while of the present Companies and their shareholders to sell, and as the result to give the nation the benefit of speedy and efficient transport at the nominal fares and rates mentioned. It will, indeed, be a “Revolution,” but one of the most beneficial that can befall a nation. The Royal Mail is an institution of which the nation is justly proud. How much more will it be so of an institution which will include the Royal Mail, namely, =Royal Railways=. CHAPTER I. THE SCHEME. This is the scheme proposed:-- The whole of the existing undertakings of all the Railway Companies in the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Ireland will be acquired by purchase on some such terms as are set out at the end of this pamphlet and vested in the Government. The whole system will be amalgamated with the General Post Office and form one of the Departments of State, of which the Postmaster-General for the time being will be the head, and probably adopt the style of “Minister of Transport,” who will be a Member of the Cabinet. =It will be expressly enacted that any profit made by the combined services shall be used only for increasing their efficiency, for payment of purchase money, or in reduction of fares and rates charged for the services, and in no case for general revenue of the country. There shall also be no prohibition of competition by private enterprise.=[1] All passenger trains will be regarded as consisting of two kinds, namely:-- (1) =Main Line Trains=, by which will be meant express trains running on the Main trunk lines between, and only stopping at, important towns. A ticket for =one shilling= will entitle the holder to enter any Main Line train at any station, and to travel in it to any other station at which it stops, and a ticket for =five shillings= will entitle him to travel first class in such trains. (2) =Local Trains=, by which will be meant all trains, other than Main Line trains as defined above, including all Metropolitan, Suburban and Branch Line trains throughout the Kingdom, as well as trains on Main lines which stop at all stations. A ticket for =one penny= will entitle the holder to enter any Local train at any station, and to travel in it to any other station at which it stops, and a ticket for =sixpence= will entitle him to travel first class in such train if that accommodation is provided. =Steamers= which form part of the railway undertakings will also be regarded as of two kinds, according to whether they form part of a Main Line, _e.g._, the Irish Packets or the Cross Channel steamers, in which case admission to them will be 1s. or 5s., according to class, or simply as part of a Branch line, _e.g._, the Isle of Wight steamers, to which admission would be 1d. or 6d. according to class. In the case of Main Line trains and steamers, additional fixed charges (the same for any distance) will be made for the use of refreshment cars, sleeping cars, State cabins, reserved seats and any other special services. In the case of Local trains, and possibly Main Line trains, =Season Tickets= may be issued, in each case available for any Main Line train or Local train as the case may be. For Local trains the following rates are suggested, viz.:-- 3rd class 1s. per week, 4s. per month, £2 per annum. 1st class 2s. 6d. ” 10s. ” £5 ” ” =Passenger Tickets= will not be issued to or from any particular stations, but like postage stamps will vary only according to the fares and special charges for the time being in force. The four denominations of 5s., 1s., 6d. and 1d. will, of course, be required, and 4s. and 5d. tickets could also be issued to make up the first class fares with the 1s. and 1d. tickets. These tickets will be sold not only at every railway station, but also at every Post Office and in automatic machines. Every railway station will be, or will contain, a Post Office, with all postal, telegraphic and telephonic facilities, and every Post Office will sell not only passenger tickets but also railway stamps for parcels, goods and live stock. =Goods traffic= will also consist of two services only, namely:-- (1) =Fast Service=, corresponding with the present service “per passenger train,” the charge for which will be an average of =ten shillings per ton for any distance=. (2) =Slow Service=, corresponding with the present service “per goods train,” the charge for which will be an average of =one shilling and sixpence per ton for any distance=. For both these services stamps will be issued of various denominations, and applied in manner now in use for the Parcels Post, with any necessary modification; for instance, the stamps might be affixed to consignment notes in the case of goods in bulk, or other suitable arrangements might be made for large quantities of goods. For the _slow_ goods traffic a regular service of goods trains will be organised so that at every town or village in the United Kingdom served by rail there may be at least one delivery and one collection daily, more populous places, of course, having more frequent services. For the _fast_ goods traffic a similar regular service will be organised, and in cases where the traffic will warrant it special fast goods trains will be run; otherwise the goods will be carried by the passenger trains. In course of time provision should be made for all trunk lines to have at least two double lines of rails, upon one of which fast trains for passengers and goods will run at uniform speeds, and at regular intervals, and upon the other the local trains and slow goods trains, also at uniform speed and at regular intervals. The present complicated system of differential rates, which vary not only according to distance but also according to the nature, quality and value of goods, and involving different rates, amounting in number literally to millions, would be swept away, the only variations in rates being in respect of such obvious matters as weight, size, whether carried in bulk or in packages, in open trucks or closed, whether requiring special care or labour in packing or otherwise. The average rates proposed would, it is believed, admit of a uniform rate for any distance for minerals and other goods carried in bulk in open trucks, of no more than the lowest rate now in force, by charging higher rates for goods requiring closed trucks and more labour in handling, still higher rates for goods of abnormal size or weight, and higher rates still for single small parcels, on account of greater proportionate expense of handling. For the small single parcels the rate might be for slow service as much as 6d. for any weight up to 1cwt. (equal to 10s. per ton), and for fast service say 1s., or possibly more, for any weight up to 1cwt., the weight being graduated downwards for parcels of greater weight as are the rates now in force for letter and parcels post. The goods traffic would be in effect an extension of the present parcels post, the present rates for which would probably be capable of very substantial reduction. These figures are put forward by way of suggestion only, and the question of terminal charges and fees for loading and unloading may have to be taken into account. Numerous details must necessarily be gone into in fixing an average uniform rate, and it is very likely that considerable modifications may be found necessary. Any such modifications, however, must be based upon the three rules set out on page 30 in order that the scheme may effect its object. FOOTNOTES [1] For reasons of these modifications of the present practice in National and Municipal Trading see Chapter IV., pp. 33-41. CHAPTER II. ADVANTAGES OF THE SCHEME. If this scheme is practicable financially (and one object of this pamphlet is to prove that this is so), then it seems almost superfluous to point out the great advantages of its adoption. It has been well said that “=transport is the life-blood of a nation=.” If circulation is impeded or restricted the whole country must suffer, and, conversely, if all obstructions and restrictions are removed the whole country must benefit. This scheme will, in effect, remove the principal obstruction to free circulation of passengers and goods, namely, expense. Cheapness of transport is “twice blessed; it blesseth him that gives and him that takes”--in other words, it enables the producer, whether agriculturist, manufacturer or merchant, to increase his market for goods, and enables the consumer who requires those goods to purchase at a lower price. It is common knowledge that agriculture in particular in this country is hampered and restricted by heavy charges for freight.[2] Under our present system the carriage of goods from abroad to London is cheaper than from the Midlands, and the foreigner has a great preference (so far as freight is concerned) over our own farmers. Fruit and fish is often thrown away on account of the cost of carriage being more than the value of the goods. On the other hand, the price of food and every commodity has been gradually increasing. With the removal of this obstruction of expense of carriage there must be an increase in the supply of goods, and increased supply means lower prices. As to passenger traffic, traders will appreciate the great benefit of nominal fares for themselves and their commercial travellers. So also will the greater part of the population, namely, those of very moderate means who are now prevented, solely on account of expense, from travelling any considerable distance, either on business or pleasure, or from visiting friends and relatives. These are some of the general advantages attending cheapness of transport, but it may be as well to point out in detail some of the very substantial economies and other special advantages to be obtained by adopting the proposed scheme. 1. ECONOMICAL ADVANTAGES. A few examples of the waste attending the present system, both of money and time will illustrate some of these advantages. =In the Strand, London=, within a few yards of each other, are the following premises:-- No. 168, Strand.--The Strand Station of the Piccadilly and Finsbury Park Tube Railway. No. 170, Strand.--Great Western Railway Receiving Office. No. 173-4, Strand.--East Strand Post Office. No. 179, Strand.--Great Northern Railway Receiving Office. No. 4, Norfolk Street, Strand, almost adjoining No. 179, Strand.--Inland Revenue Office. No. 183, Strand.--Midland Railway and London and North Western Railway Receiving Office. Within sight, at the other end of Norfolk Street, is the Temple Station District Railway, and at 6, Catherine Street, about the same distance from the other side of the Strand, is a Labour Exchange. It is assumed that the rents of shops in the Strand would average about £500 per annum. Under the proposed scheme, the whole of the business transacted at the above eight premises could, with greater convenience, be carried on at the two railway stations, possibly with some extensions, but with a saving not only of rent but also of rates, taxes and other outgoings. =At Bexhill-on-Sea=, with a population of only about 15,500, there are two large railway stations, one belonging to the South Eastern & Chatham Railway Company, the other to the London, Brighton & South Coast Railway Company, and situate about a mile apart. Half a mile from each is the Head Post Office, within a few doors from one of the stations is a branch Post Office, and within a small radius are Government offices for Inland Revenue and other purposes. Letters posted at a pillar box outside the station are collected there, taken to the Head Post Office for sorting, then returned with others to the railway for the Mail train leaving the same station. The majority of the passengers are for London, and go by the two different routes, but the fares are identical, and the time occupied is about the same, no advantage being gained by the public through the so-called competition. If both stations were amalgamated one staff only would be required, there would be ample room on the premises to accommodate the Head Post Office with sorting rooms, etc. (the branch office now near the station would not be required), and there would be plenty of room also for the Government Offices. In addition to the saving of expense, there would also be the great convenience and saving of time in the transport of, and dealing with, mails, passengers and goods. These two examples with many others have come under my personal observation, and they may be multiplied ten thousand times throughout the United Kingdom. Where is there a railway station, whether a great London terminus, or small provincial station, where postal facilities are available; while just outside rents are paid, in some cases very heavy ones, for other premises, to and from which the mails have to be conveyed? Other examples of waste under the present system, although not so apparent to the public, are well-known to the railway expert, and involve much greater expenditure of time and money. I refer in particular to the =waste of rolling stock=, especially of goods wagons, occasioned by the multiplicity of goods stations, the transfer of rolling stock to and from the lines of different railway companies, the shunting of trains, and the large number of road vans used by the various companies. In London alone there are 74 goods stations, used for goods only, and 700 goods trains per day travel between these 74 stations, doing nothing but transferring goods from one of these stations to another! Goods consigned to one warehouse in London from places on, say, seven different railway companies’ lines are sent by seven different vans, one belonging to each company. Under my proposed scheme one or two central goods stations of large area would not only suffice, but would provide a far more efficient and speedy transport service, and yet with the nominal rates referred to. Under the present system goods trains, having been unloaded, must be returned in order to clear the line, so that it is not uncommon to find goods trains belonging to the various companies returning empty for long distances on each line, on the G. W. R. as far as Bristol, on the S. W. R. to Basingstoke, on the G. C. R. to Banbury, and so on. It has been estimated that of the 1,400,000 goods wagons now on the railways of the United Kingdom, no more than 3 per cent. are actually in effective use at one time, the remaining 97 per cent. being either stationary or running empty![3] One reason for this, no doubt, is the use of merely hand labour for loading and unloading. With a view to avoiding this waste the New Transport Company, Limited was registered in 1908, for the purpose of introducing new and ingenious machinery, invented by Mr. A. W. Gattie and Mr. A. G. Seaman, for handling goods, including the adoption of movable “containers” on trucks and wagons, and a scheme for a “Goods Clearing House” occupying a site of about 30 acres, in Clerkenwell, to be connected by rail with all the lines coming to London. It is, of course, necessary, in order to carry so important a scheme into effect to negotiate with all the various railway companies interested, as well as to obtain an Act of Parliament. Besides this, a large amount of capital is required for the acquisition of the site, the construction of the connecting lines, installation of the machinery, etc. Notwithstanding the large cost, estimated by Mr. Edgar Harper, F.S.S., late Statistical Officer of the London County Council, at £14,000,000, he shows that such a system would more than pay for itself in a year by the economies in transport which it would effect directly or indirectly. No estimate, however, is given, nor probably can be given by anyone, of the time that will be occupied in carrying such a scheme into effect, so long as this present system of numerous companies and conflicting interests continues. Five years have already gone by since the Company was registered. If, however, the scheme of nationalisation and amalgamation with the Post Office be adopted, there should be no difficulty in providing as part of such scheme for the system and machinery of the New Transport Company already referred to, not only in London but in every other traffic centre. It might also be possible to avoid the expense of acquiring a new site for a “Goods Clearing House” by utilising some portion of the large area occupied by the three large termini and approaches thereto of King’s Cross, St. Pancras and Euston. There will then be no conflicting interests, no multiplicity of companies, and no difficulty in raising the necessary capital for establishing the system, and what is still more important, no difficulty, as will be shown hereafter under the heading of “Finance,” in producing the necessary revenue to repay the capital and interest, by reason of the progressively increasing traffic which will result from the adoption of the small uniform average rates advocated. The following, then, are some of the very substantial economies which will be effected by my scheme:-- =I. Expenditure which would be entirely abolished=:-- (_a_) The Railway Clearing House, the sole object of which is to apportion receipts and payments between the various companies, about 217 in number, and requiring for its work a large and expensive staff, not only of clerks, but also of inspectors at every junction, and a large establishment at Seymour Street, Euston. (_b_) The separate Boards of Directors, officers, and clerical staff of all the separate companies. (_c_) The legal and parliamentary expenses incurred in disputes between the various companies, and in opposing rival companies’ new lines. (_d_) Advertisements by rival companies of their own routes. =II. Expenditure and waste which would be diminished=:-- =1. By reason of unification of systems.= (_a_) Competing receiving offices and their staffs would be reduced to one in each locality. (_b_) Rolling stock, which is now often idle because owned by different companies, could be used solely according to the requirements of the traffic. (_c_) Competing trains now running on different lines at the same time between London and other large towns could be run at different times with largely increased numbers of passengers at same cost. (_d_) Adjoining stations belonging to competing companies would be amalgamated. =2. By reason of the adoption of uniform rates and fares.= (_a_) The abolition of the elaborate book-keeping and staffs needful for the present complicated system of passengers’ fares and goods rates, especially the latter, with the waste not only of expense but also of time. (_b_) The saving of the expense of printing and advertising various priced tickets and fare tables, also of the large staff of booking clerks, inspectors and others. (_c_) The saving of the legal expenses now incurred by the Railway and Canal Commission Court in appeals and disputes between the companies and traders as to rates, etc. =3. By reason of the amalgamation of railways with the Post Office.= (_a_) The rent and expenses of numerous Post Offices in the neighbourhood of railway stations would be saved, all stations being used for postal purposes. (_b_) All postal sorting and other offices could be situate on railway premises in or near the stations, and besides thus saving the rent would be in closer touch with the railway. (_c_) The whole of the railway tracks would be available without rent for laying of telegraph and telephone wires, either over or underground. (_d_) Surplus land of the railways, in particular where adjoining to stations, would be available for other Government purposes, such as Inland Revenue Offices, Labour Exchanges, Military, Naval or Civil Service purposes, Police Stations, Fire Stations, County Courts, Police Courts, Land Courts, as well as Courts for dealing with questions arising out of the railways themselves. 2. GENERAL ADVANTAGES. Unification enables each part of the country to have as good a service of trains as every other part, notwithstanding differences of population and resources. The Companies now operating on the South Coast cannot provide so good a service as the Northern Companies owing to the lack of the great mining and industrial centres which are served by the latter. One of the most conspicuous examples of this is =Ireland=. A Royal Commission was sitting for many years on the question of Irish railways, and ultimately reported in favour of State acquisition. Even this, it is clear, would not entirely solve the difficulty, which arises from the natural causes of being an island with (compared to the rest of Great Britain) a small population, mostly agricultural. If, however, the Irish railways were amalgamated with all the others of the United Kingdom under the proposed scheme the problem is solved. In the estimate given in considering the finance of the scheme the Irish railways are included. The conversion of the railway system into Government property will, apart from the question of economy already referred to, provide a most important advantage to the State. For example, the War Office can make use of the railway system, not only for the purposes of transport, but for the erection on surplus land throughout the country of barracks, stores, and other buildings, for wireless telegraph stations and for aviation purposes. The Admiralty will have the use of the great docks and wharves now owned by railways. The Civil Service will also find ample space for additional office accommodation, often in the most convenient spots both in town and country. Still more important even than these advantages is the fact that by the removal of all money restrictions from transport, not only an immediate but a =progressive increase of traffic= will result. That this will be so is shown hereafter when considering the question of the finance of the scheme, but it is referred to here as one of the most important advantages of the scheme, apart from the benefits to the nation already referred to of free circulation of passengers and goods. In the first place, the increase of traffic will require in all probability the whole of the staff now employed, who would otherwise be thrown out of employment by reason of the economies referred to above. It will be noticed that in the estimates given under the heading of “Finance of the Scheme” no decrease, but on the contrary, a slight increase has been estimated for in the working expenses, notwithstanding the enormous saving to be anticipated by the abolition and reduction of wasteful expenditure under the present system. My reason for so doing is partly to err on the side of caution in the estimates, but also to provide for the probability of having to retain the whole of the existing staff, and possibly increasing their wages and reducing their hours of labour. Most of the economies referred to must necessarily be effected gradually; for instance, the clerical staffs of the various railway companies and of the Railway Clearing House would be required for some considerable time in the process of winding-up, and by the time this is finished the traffic will have still further increased and their work will then be required in the more necessary departments of, say, the Goods Clearing Houses throughout the country. Secondly, the progressive increase of traffic will produce a corresponding increase of revenue which will be available for extensions and additions, for electrification of lines, and other improvements in means of transport, and ultimately even in still further reduction in charges, but last and by no means least in the adoption of appliances and inventions for the safety of life and limb both of passengers and railway servants. Unlike the present companies, the Government will have no difficulty in raising the capital required for any such purposes, and in relying upon the inevitable increase of traffic, as now is the case of the Post Office, for repayment. Take the case of automatic couplings. These were invented 40 years ago[4] and their adoption has been urged on the companies ever since, not only on the merciful ground of saving life and limb, but also on the financial ground of saving waste of time in shunting; but the initial expense of fitting these to every truck and carriage has been too much for the directors of the Companies to risk. Many inventions for automatic signalling, instantaneous brakes, and other life-saving appliances have been from time to time submitted to railway companies, but the initial expense of installation throughout the many miles of railway of each company has been so great that one hardly wonders at the hesitation of directors in laying out money belonging to the shareholders, especially when, notwithstanding a small normal increase of traffic, the working expenses have increased to a greater degree. FOOTNOTES [2] See “The Rural Problem,” by H. D. Harben (Constable & Co., 1913, 2s. 6d.). Mr. Balfour Browne, K.C., also, in addressing the London Chamber of Commerce, February, 1897, said, “I am not exaggerating when I say that the Agricultural question … is nothing else but a question of Railway Rates.” [3] Lecture by A. W. Gattie, at London School of Economics, 11th March, 1913. [4] “Mammon’s Victims,” by T. A. Brocklebank, published by C. W. Daniel, 1911--Price 6d. CHAPTER III. THE PRINCIPLES UPON WHICH THE SCHEME IS BASED. At first sight it seems preposterous that the fare =from London to Glasgow should be only one shilling=, the same as from London to Brighton, or that the fare of one penny from Mansion House to Victoria should be the same as from Victoria to Croydon. To a railway expert it will doubtless appear still more preposterous that the rate for a ton of iron-ore should be the same as for a ton of manufactured iron, and that the rate for general merchandise should be as low as 1s. 6d. per ton for any distance; and yet it is now considered a matter of course that the rate of 1d. for 4 ozs. for a letter from London to Londonderry should be the same as from one part of London to another, or 3d. for 1 lb. should be the rate by parcel post for any distance great or small, and irrespective of what the contents of the parcel may be. The system of charging for transport =according to distance=, which is still in force throughout the civilised world, except in the Postal Service, appears to me to be =founded on a wrong principle=. It has no doubt been adopted on the assumption that the greater the cost of production the greater should be the charge, and, therefore, that as it costs more to build 100 miles of railway than one mile, and takes more coal or electric current to haul a train for 100 miles than for one mile, it is necessary to charge more for the longer distance. Even the Post Office still clings to the same idea, in charging higher rates for the telephone trunk service according to distance, although the charges for telegrams are the same for any distance! It is significant that whereas the net profits from railways remain more or less stationary, that of the Post Office with uniform rates continually increases, and that the telephone system with charges according to distance is so far the least satisfactory branch of the Post Office. It is no doubt a general rule that the price of an article depends upon the cost of production, but when dealing with transport the analogy fails. In the case of a national system of railways the provision of a regular service of trains to and from all parts of the country is a necessity. Such a service requires that trains must run at stated intervals advertised beforehand from one terminus to another, say from A to Z, with various stopping places between those points, which may be represented by other letters of the alphabet. The cost of running each train will be the same, whether it contains 20 passengers or 200, whether some or all of the passengers alight from or board the train at any intermediate station or at either terminus. Therefore, the actual cost of carrying a passenger from A to Z is not, in fact, more than from A to B, or from M to Z. The same consideration applies to goods with even greater force. With goods the cost of handling them has to be considered, as well as the cost of haulage. If goods are sent from A to B only they must be handled twice, and this is no more than if they are sent from A to Z, assuming there is no need for change of trucks. In the case of goods under the present system there is a further principle acted upon, which is still more obviously a wrong one, _viz._, what is known as charging =according to “what the traffic will bear.”= This term is well known to all railway experts, and is a convenient way of explaining the reasons governing the various rates under the present system. For instance, if too high a rate is charged for goods of comparatively small value, traders prefer to send by the cheaper modes, namely, by sea or by road, and in many cases it would not be worth while to send at all, whereas in the case of an article like silk or bullion of considerable value the extra cost of carriage even at a high rate would not add appreciably to the price. Therefore, the railway companies are compelled to make lower charges for low-priced goods, otherwise they would lose the traffic altogether. Accordingly there are such anomalies as a higher rate for the carriage of manufactured iron than of iron-ore for the same distance, although the cost of trucks, of haulage, and of handling may be identical. Again, the rate for carriage of meat from the Midlands to London is greater than that from Liverpool to London, partly on account of the competition of the sea, and partly on account of the large consignments of foreign meat. Again, the rate for the carriage of bricks from one part of London to another is greater than from Peterborough to London, because Peterborough is in a brick-producing district. These inconsistencies and anomalies are intensified by the necessity of the goods having to be carried over the lines of several different railway companies, all of whom must receive some profit out of the carriage of the goods, in addition to the actual cost. It is quite clear that the actual cost of haulage for the same distance of say a ton of coal is no more than that of a ton of bricks or of manufactured iron, or of sand, or of a pantechnicon full of furniture, all of which can be carried in open trucks, yet the rates for all these various goods, even for the same distance, differ widely from each other under the present system, and differ again not only according to distance but actually according to the different towns between which the service is rendered. Many examples of the present anomalies are strikingly shown by Mr. Emil Davies in his book, “The Case for Railway Nationalisation,”[5] which should be read by all interested in the subject. Now assume that the whole of the various existing railways are amalgamated; that Main line trains both for goods and passengers run at regular intervals to and from the principal towns; that Local trains run from station to station and on branch lines also at regular intervals, connecting at junctions with Main line trains; that just as there are now regular times for delivery and collections of letters and parcels by post, varying in number according to the population of each locality, so there are regular collections and deliveries of goods to and from every town and village in the United Kingdom; and that a uniform rate, no more than, or even less than, the smallest rate now charged, is all that has to be paid. It is true that with such a system at many of the smaller places the actual expense of collection and delivery may, indeed, be “more than the traffic would bear,” certainly much more than the Directors of a railway company would feel warranted in risking under the present system with their necessarily limited area, but when these smaller places are part of such a system as is here described, extending to every town in the United Kingdom, then the whole becomes self-supporting, and there is no advantage in charging, either according to distance, or according to “what the traffic will bear.” Every little village Post Office in the United Kingdom is an object-lesson to us. Here we have all the resources of civilisation, letter and parcel post, telegraph, telephone, savings bank, money orders, all provided at exactly the same rate as in the largest Cities of the Empire. Although the actual expense of each village Post Office taken by itself is out of all proportion to the population of the district, the combination of all of them in one national unified system enables these remote villages to benefit, not only with no financial loss to the nation, but actually with a handsome net profit which has actually contributed to the general revenue of the nation. This was not contemplated when the Penny Post was established, and is a practice which, in my view, is a great mistake, as explained in Chapter IV. The same principle has been applied to the ordinary roads of the country, which are now open free of charge to the whole population, although many of this generation can still remember the restrictions of the old toll-gates. It is only applying the same principle to the nation which applies to the human body. “The body is not one member, but many.… Whether one member suffers, all the members suffer with it, or one member be honoured, all the members rejoice with it.” If from any cause, such as a flood or other physical disturbance a small industrial or agricultural district were cut off from all communication with the rest of the Country, it is not only that district but also the whole of the Country which suffers loss, namely, the loss of trade with that district. And if by reason of high rates the remote towns, villages, and districts, as well as those nearer to great centres, are prevented from obtaining an outlet for their produce, the whole Country suffers. The converse is equally true: as soon as free circulation of passengers and goods is provided, the prosperity of the whole Country as well as of each district is increased. This, then, is the principle upon which the scheme of uniform fares and rates is founded, as opposed to the existing system of charging according to distance and according to “what the traffic will bear.” There remains, however, to be considered the principle upon which the particular uniform fares and rates mentioned on the title page have been suggested for the proposed scheme. These have not been selected at haphazard, but in accordance with three rules which, I believe, are founded upon a sound principle, namely:-- =(1) That any flat rate to be successful must not exceed the minimum rate in force prior to the adoption of the scheme=; =(2) That there should result from the change a sufficient increase of traffic to produce at least the same net revenue as before=; =(3) That in a system of transport the fares and rates should vary, not according to distance travelled, but according to speed of service.= In accordance with these rules I take =for Passenger Traffic= first the present minimum railway fare now charged, that is, 1d. for short distances of one mile or under. If the flat rate were fixed at say 2d., or, indeed, any sum over 1d., passengers who now pay that sum would have to pay at least double the existing fare; this would, of course, render the whole scheme impracticable. On the other hand, under a flat rate of 1d. throughout the whole country the receipts would not be sufficient to produce the present revenue unless and until the number of passengers carried should increase by as much as six or seven times. That this is so is clear when it is remembered that the =present average railway fare for the whole of the United Kingdom= (allowing for season ticket holders), =is 6½d.= In other words, if all the passengers now travelling would pay 6½d. for every journey, both for short ones, as from Mansion House to Charing Cross, and long ones, as from London to Londonderry, then the same gross revenue from passengers would be obtained as now; or, on the other hand, if a flat rate of 1d. any distance were fixed, and the number of passenger journeys were increased by six-and-a-half times as a result of this great reduction, then, again, the same gross revenue would be obtained. The first of these alternatives is, of course, impracticable, and the second one is certainly not likely to be attained for some time to come, and even then account would have to be taken of the additional working expenses occasioned by so large an increase of traffic. It is on account of these difficulties that any system of uniform fares has hitherto been regarded as impracticable. The solution of this problem was suggested to me by the practice of the Post Office of charging 3d. for express delivery, and 6d. for a telegram. Here we have the third rule before referred to of charging according to speed of service. Applying this to railways, and again searching for the lowest fares now charged for fast Main line trains, it will be observed that these are the regular cheap excursion fares of 2s. 6d. from London to Brighton or Southend and back, which amounts to 1s. 3d. each way. It is true that these are exceptionally cheap fares. Return tickets only are issued at this price, available by certain trains only, but on the principle already laid down that the flat rate must not exceed the lowest, this forms the basis of the proposed uniform fare of 1s. for Main line trains. Although this uniform fare is so exceptionally low, it is still nearly double the present average fare, and it is precisely on the Main line trains that increase of traffic (now restricted by expense) is sure to take place. These facts (as will appear in the chapter, “Finance of the Scheme”) enable me to estimate the increase of passenger traffic required to make up the present gross revenue at only 15 per cent. of the present number of passengers carried. =For goods traffic= the uniform rates suggested have been ascertained in accordance with the same rules. It is more difficult to ascertain the present minimum owing to the enormous complication of goods rates. Under the present system, goods are divided into eight different classes according to the rate charged, and a maximum rate is fixed by law for each class. In the lowest of these classes the rates vary from one penny and a fraction up to 4d. per ton per mile for any distance up to 20 miles, and smaller proportionate rates for distances over 20 miles. But although these are the greatest amounts that the companies may charge for this class of goods, they do make special rates of considerably lower amounts for special kinds of goods. It is estimated that five-sevenths of all the goods carried are charged according to special rates not included in the eight classes mentioned. The Board of Trade returns give the totals of two classes of goods only, namely, “minerals,” of which 410 million tons are carried, and “general merchandise,” of which only 116 million tons are carried. These returns are possibly misleading as, although derived from returns made by the several companies themselves, it may be that those returns include the same goods sent over different lines. For the purposes of my estimates, however, I have assumed that the Board of Trade returns are correct, and if they are so, the average charge for “minerals” is now about 1s. 6d. per ton, and for “general merchandise” about 6s. per ton. Taking the two classes of goods traffic together, as representing what under my scheme will be the “slow goods traffic,” =the average is only 2s. 4d. per ton=. The average rate of 1s. 6d. per ton has been suggested for the slow service because it is believed that this average will allow of a rate for all goods in open trucks as small as the lowest rate now charged for minerals for short distances, the average being maintained by higher rates chargeable for other kinds of goods as already described. If the actual tonnage of goods carried is really less than that mentioned in the official returns (it cannot be more), it may be found necessary to fix a somewhat higher uniform rate, and the estimates may be affected to a certain degree. The figures, especially those relating to goods traffic, are put forward by way of suggestion only, and there should be no difficulty in ascertaining a uniform rate in accordance with the rules already stated. It is believed that any difficulty in this respect will be solved by the large accession of traffic by Fast service, which, as with Main line passengers, is sure to follow the adoption of the scheme. The average rate for “fast” service has been obtained by ascertaining the lowest rate now charged for goods carried “per passenger train.” This appears to be the rate for returned empties for any distance up to 25 miles, namely, 6d. per cwt. (equals 10s. per ton). There is also a charge of £1 for a load not exceeding 2 1/2 tons on carriage trucks attached to a passenger train for a distance of 40 miles, and thereafter at 6d. a mile. It is evident that an average of 10s. per ton would allow of a still smaller rate than that amount for goods carried in bulk and in large consignments. FOOTNOTES [5] “The Case for Railway Nationalisation” by Emil Davies, published by Collins, 1913--Price 1s. CHAPTER IV. OBJECTIONS TO THE SCHEME. I now propose to consider objections which may be raised to the proposed scheme. I anticipate opposition from those who object to all forms of =State Ownership= or State Management. The late Lord Avebury was one of the most prominent opponents of nationalisation, and his views are set out in his book “On Municipal and National Trading.”[6] Mr. Edwin A. Pratt has written several books on the subject and has recently collected all the arguments up to date against State Ownership in his book, “The Case against Railway Nationalisation,”[7] In this book examples are given of the experience of foreign countries and the Colonies where railways have been taken over by the State. Other writers who have advocated the retention of our present system, and are quoted with approval by Lord Avebury, are the following:-- Messrs. G. Foxwell and T. C. Farrer (now Lord Farrer), in “Express Trains, English and Foreign.” (1889); Mr. W. M. Acworth, in “The Railways and the Traders”; Mr. H. R. Meyer, in “Government Regulation of Railway Rates,” and in “Railway Rates”; and Lord Farrer and Mr. Giffin, in “The State in its Relation to Trade.” On the other side, the following, among other advocates of railway nationalisation have shown the great advantages to be anticipated by such a measure, and have given very cogent answers to the objections of the opponents, namely:-- Mr. William Cunningham, “Railway Nationalisation.” (Published by himself at Dunfermline, 1906, 2s. 6d.); Mr. Clement Edwards, M.P., “Railway Nationalisation.” (Methuen & Co., 1907, 2s. 6d.); and Mr. Emil Davies in several books, including his latest, already referred to, “The Case for Railway Nationalisation.” (Collins, 1913, 1s.) But in all these books, and in other books and articles, both for and against nationalisation, it has been assumed that if, and when, the railways are acquired by the State, the same system will obtain as now, and as obtains in the case of all the foreign countries and colonies referred to, namely, =to charge according to distance and according to “what the traffic will bear,” and with the primary object of making the most profit=. With very great deference to all these distinguished writers, it appears to me that they have one and all overlooked the fundamental principles which should be acted upon by a State or a Municipality first in deciding whether or not to acquire a monopoly, and secondly, in the administration of it when acquired. These principles depend upon =the fundamental difference between the objects in view, and actuating a Company or individual on the one hand and a Nation or Municipality on the other in acquiring a monopoly=. In the former case the =sole object= is that of =pecuniary gain or profit=; in the latter the =sole object= is, or ought to be, the =benefit of the community=. It may be said that these are not respectively the sole objects, but only the =primary objects=. My reply is that in the case of the company it is the duty of the directors, as trustees for the shareholders, to so carry on the business in question as to produce the most profit, irrespective of any benefit to the community, or, indeed, to any persons other than the shareholders. Railway companies, it is true, provide the benefit of transport, and various advantages held out by the companies as inducements to use their particular lines, but these are, of course, solely offered with the view of increasing the profits. Other advantages for the comfort, safety and benefit of the public are provided under compulsion from the Government, as a condition of the grant of privileges and compulsory powers conferred upon the companies, without which the railways could not have been made. I refer to such matters as rules and regulations for the safety and benefit of the public; workmen’s trains; maximum fares and rates allowed to be charged; provision for at least one train a day at all stations, etc. Conversely, in the case of a Nation or Municipality taking over a monopoly, it is the duty of the Government Department or Town Council to so carry on the business as to render the most efficient service, at the lowest cost consistent with efficiency, with paying for the cost of acquisition and with paying the working expenses. Advocates of nationalisation urge that profits should be applied in reduction of taxation, and suggest that this is in itself one of the benefits to be derived therefrom. Opponents always assume that national and municipal trading must be carried on with a view to profit, and some even ridicule the idea that any trading concern can be successfully carried on unless with this view and with a resulting profit. Acrimonious discussions have taken place as to whether profits which have been claimed by advocates of municipal trading to have been made by tramways, gas, water and electricity works, are only paper profits as alleged by the opponents. In Lord Avebury’s book already referred to,[8] one whole chapter, headed “Loss and Profit,” treats of the question whether municipal enterprises have been profitable or not, and he adduces many examples to prove that in most cases the alleged profits are imaginary. It has, in fact, been the practice universally to apply profits made out of municipal trading in this Country in reduction of rates, and in foreign Countries, where railways are owned by the State, their revenues are made use of either as general revenue or, as in Prussia, for social or educational purposes, which would otherwise be provided for by direct taxation. The only instance of national trading in this Country is the General Post Office, and I think it is correct to say that the original intention when Penny Post was established was to so carry it on that working expenses only should be covered by the revenue. In practice, the gross revenue is entered with other items of revenue in the National Accounts, and the gross expenditure with other items of general and non-productive expenditure, with the result that the net profits of the Post Office, in effect, become a source of general revenue, and are therefore applied in reduction of general taxation. Until recent years this net profit has not been considerable, but last year it was as much as £5,000,000. Having regard to the continual and progressive increase in postal business, and the acquisition of the whole telephone system, there is every prospect of still further increase in net profits. What will be the result of a continuance of this practice of applying net profits of Municipal and National trading towards reduction of rates and taxes? It has not, so far, had any very serious result, simply on account of the fact that such net profits have not yet been of a very startling amount. But if these profits should increase, will not the result be the very evils which are the natural consequence of a private monopoly? Once the principle is admitted that profits from such trading shall go in relief of taxation, the service will, and must, be worked more or less with the primary object of making as much profit as possible, with the inevitable result that the service in question will be starved for the sake of the profits. This has actually happened in the case of the Prussian State Railways, the one State Railway which has so far made the greatest net profit. In addition to this difficulty there are others inherent in State or Municipal trading, if the principle of making profits be admitted, and if profits are actually made. In such a case the Chancellor of the Exchequer will be expected to budget for further profits, the general public will expect improvements in the service, traders will expect that the charges to them should be reduced, and the workers will expect that their wages should be increased. This view is not a new one. It has been advocated in respect of the Post Office for many years by such well-known postal reformers as Lord Eversley (formerly Mr. Shaw Lefevre), and Sir Henniker Heaton, Bart. The latter, I believe, has several times moved resolutions in the House of Commons for the express purpose of having the postal profit applied to the use of the Post Office itself, instead of to general revenue. It is well known that “=strikes=” are more likely to arise in a period of trade prosperity. It is the natural result of the workers seeing large profits made out of their industry, if they should have no benefit, by increase of wages, by sharing in such profits or otherwise. It makes but little difference to the workers that those profits go to ratepayers, instead of to shareholders, more especially as they usually inhabit houses let on weekly inclusive rentals, and are exempt from income-tax, so that they do not directly pay either rates or taxes. If, on the other hand, the profits are devoted to improving the efficiency of the service or cheapening the charges, then, not only are there no profits to excite the cupidity of various sections of the community, but the workers do, in fact, benefit by themselves and their families, as well as the whole of the public for whom the services are worked. No strike is ever successful which does not gain general public support, and even under existing conditions there is much less likelihood of strikes in the case of Civil Servants or postal or municipal employees, partly on account of the better wages paid, the certainty of continuing in employment except for misconduct, and the prospects of a pension, but still more on account of the practical certainty that public support would not be given to a strike which interferes with one of the most important of the public services.[9] Another evil of ignoring the difference in principle of a public monopoly and a private monopoly has been the practice of applying to public monopolies the practice which all private monopolies endeavour to achieve (and properly so as their sole object is profit), namely, to put down all possible competition. If the principle I advocate, namely, that the =sole object of a public monopoly is the benefit of the community=, then if some improvement in the service, the subject of such monopoly, shall be invented, which is proved to be practicable, the public should have the benefit of such improvement, and, =instead of a prohibition of such private enterprise every encouragement should be given= to it. In our Navy, when new inventions are found which increase its efficiency, no time or money is lost in adopting them, even at the expense of discarding comparatively modern men-of-war or appliances. The risk to the nation of not doing so is too great to allow considerations of expense to stand in the way. But what has happened in the case of so important a commercial matter as the Telephone? The Post Office are authorised by Act of Parliament to forbid any competition, a provision evidently enacted under the impression that a public monopoly must have Statutory protection against competition, which a private monopoly always seeks to obtain, but has to pay for. Having this monopoly, and having purchased the telegraphs, the Post Office from the first regarded telephones with the utmost jealousy, because it seemed likely to interfere with its “Profits”! Lord Avebury quotes from “The Times” of 13th June, 1884, as follows:--[10] “… the action of the Post Office has been so directed as to throw every possible difficulty in the way of the development of the telephone, and of its constant employment by the public. We say advisedly, ‘every possible difficulty,’ because the regulations under which licences have been granted to the telephone companies are in many respects as completely prohibitory as an absolute refusal of them.” “… the effects of this claim are nearly as disastrous to the Country as to the inventors and owners of the instruments.” When it is remembered that the Post Office insisted on being paid one-tenth, not of the profits, but of the gross receipts, the wonder is that our telephone system is not more backward than it is. Lord Avebury, of course, uses this and other instances, such as the opposition of municipalities owning tramway and gas undertakings, to tramway extensions in adjoining districts, and licences to motor omnibuses and also to the introduction of electricity for lighting and power, as an argument against nationalisation and municipal trading.[11] That these constitute a strong argument against public monopolies being worked for profit, I readily admit, but they do not weaken the argument that all such concerns which must, in their very nature, be incapable of effective competition, should be taken over by the community, and be worked solely for its benefit. What possible chance is there of competition in a telephone system? It is, of course, an essential element to its success that each subscriber should be able to communicate with every other one. How, then, can it ever have been imagined that there could be any effective competition between rival systems? And yet competition was actually attempted between various municipalities and the National Telephone Company, and afterwards the Post Office itself was authorised to “compete” with that Company. The ultimate purchase by the State was, of course, a foregone conclusion, but at what expense of both time and money has this at length been effected! The complaints which have been made since the completion of this purchase are evidently the result, not of nationalisation, but of the mistaken practice followed in a fruitless attempt at making or retaining so-called “profits” of the telegraph system, by at first putting “every possible difficulty” in the way of telephones, then attempting to compete with them, and then waiting a number of years before completing the purchase, with the result of being compelled to take over a large number of obsolete plant and instruments, and linking them up with a new system, thus producing a state of confusion and useless expenditure of time and money, which could all have been avoided by purchase of the patents and patent rights more than 30 years ago. It is only right to say that Lord Avebury was still of opinion in 1907 that the resolution of the Government to buy up the National Telephone Company was “an extraordinary and most unfortunate policy.”[12] Mr. Hanbury, who was the Minister mainly responsible in 1906 for the purchase of the telephones, had evidently changed his opinion since 1889, when, in answer to a deputation in favour of purchasing the telephones, he said, according to a report quoted by Lord Avebury from “The Times”:-- “If the telephone service was cast upon the Post Office it would be to the detriment of both the postal and telegraph services. Then, again, it would increase enormously the Government staff. He need only appeal to the Members of Parliament present to say whether they would like to have the weekly appeals for increase of wages from those State servants still further extended.” Here we have exactly one of the arguments which is now being used against railway nationalisation, and by the very Minister who, 17 years after, did the very thing he had clearly condemned. I admit the argument would hold good if the restriction be not imposed by an inflexible rule that there should be no attempt to work the concern, whether Post Office, telephone, railway or other monopoly for purposes of profit. I have already referred to the mistake the Post Office are making in following the example of the private monopolist, the National Telephone Company, in charging for telephones according to distance, although between the very same towns in which different rates are charged the same department charges 6d. only for telegrams! This can only be with the strange, yet futile, intention of making more profit without regard to the benefit of the community. If the same rate were charged for Trunk calls as for local calls, many more provincial and country people would subscribe, and the wires being already laid and exchanges established, the additional expense would be but small. It would seem, indeed, that the search after profits in the case of Government or municipal monopolies is as futile as the search by people after happiness, personified by Maeterlinck as “The Blue Bird,” and that when the only object is to benefit the community, the profits come, as does happiness, when the only object is that of benefiting other people. Now, in considering the principle here laid down, it appears to me that there are four rules which should be observed when a nation or municipality undertakes anything in the nature of a trading concern:-- 1. Only such concerns should be taken over as are, and must be, =in the very nature of things, a monopoly=, or, in other words, are not susceptible of effective competition. 2. Any such concern taken over should be worked with =the sole object in view of benefiting the community= and, therefore, the charges made should be so adjusted as to pay for the acquisition of the concern and for working expenses, and any surplus from time to time applied, only in improving the efficiency of the undertaking, or in reducing the charges made. 3. In the event of any invention or improvement being made, and proved to be commercially successful, whereby the benefit to the community can be increased, and provided the concern remains in its nature a monopoly, such improvements should be taken over and worked by the State or municipality, and meantime =there should be no prohibition of any private enterprise carried on in competition= apparent or real. 4. All such concerns, whether national or municipal, should be worked or directed by one or more Department of State, having at its head a Minister, who should be a Member of the Cabinet, and =responsible to the House of Commons, and as such liable to a vote of censure for any abuse or want of efficiency in the concern=. As to Rule No. 1, there appears sometimes to be a very thin line between what is, and is not, susceptible of effective competition. As a general rule, =any concern which involves a right or easement over land, must be in the nature of a monopoly=. Thus the supply of gas, water and electricity, all of which must be conveyed by pipes or wires into houses, are in the nature of a monopoly, but the fittings used in the houses are not, but are susceptible of very efficient competition, both as to workmanship, manufacture and design. All roads, including railroads and tramways, are, and must be, in the nature of a monopoly, but the manufacture of materials and rolling stock, the catering of hotels, forming part of the railway undertakings, or in the trains themselves, or in railway steamers, are all the subject of effective competition and should, therefore, be put up for competition with special supervision and restrictions against abuse of the privileges obtained by competition on Government property. Now, I would ask any unprejudiced reader who has studied the writings of the eminent authors already quoted, and other opponents of nationalisation, to read those books again with these four rules in his mind, and consider whether all the objections so forcibly brought forward against nationalisation would not be very nearly, if not completely, answered, if such nationalisation were carried out with strict adherence to these rules. I venture to think that Lord Avebury himself would have admitted the force of this contention. It would, at least, answer the question he puts more than once, “Where, indeed, is it (municipal and national trading) to stop? Is it to stop at all?… It is sometimes said that the line should be drawn at necessaries. But if so, to light, gas, water and tramways, we should have to add bread, meat, fire insurance, … etc., while many would also add tobacco, tea and beer.”[13] In effect, the whole of the objections to State ownership, as will appear from a perusal of the various books referred to above, and the arguments of other opponents, are all comprised under three heads, namely, according to the relationship of the State:-- 1. With traders. 2. With railway servants. 3. With the general public, especially on such matters as officialism and inefficiency, owing to want of competition, bad administration, and interference with private enterprise. The first of the two objections referred to is that the Government would be in the great difficulty of having to meet the conflicting interests of traders and merchants on the one hand, and the general public on the other, with continual disputes as to the claims of various parties, and possible attempts to bring influence to bear on the Government and Members of Parliament. This objection was raised by the Prime Minister recently in reply to a deputation supporting railway nationalisation. The difficulty has been found in countries where railways are State owned, and would, I admit, be a most serious objection, if, after nationalisation, the railways should be worked on the same principle as now, namely, with the object of making the most profit possible, and charging according to “what the traffic will bear.” The objection, however, disappears if the proposed rules are adhered to, especially when, as in the proposed scheme, fares and rates are fixed irrespective of distance, locality, class of traders or goods, and in which, therefore, no question of preference or, indeed, of any conflicting interests can arise. As to the second heading, affecting the relationship of the State with the railway servants. It is suggested that the railway servants (who would, on nationalisation, become Civil servants) could use their voting powers to exact undue privileges for themselves which they cannot now obtain, and that serious abuses might arise owing to the great political power exercised by a large increase in the number of voters who are also Civil servants. This does not appear to me so formidable an objection as the first, but it is quite possible that a large united body of Civil servants might have power to so influence the Government as to extract higher wages or less hours, if they discovered that by their exertions a very large profit was derived by the railway system. Some writers have gone so far as to suggest that all persons employed by Government should be disfranchised. Others suggest that special representatives of Government officials should be returned to Parliament. Others that all such officials should take the same oath of allegiance as soldiers, and, in short, become subject to military discipline. In two articles appearing recently in the “Westminster Gazette,” under the title of “Unrest in the Railway World, by an Expert,”[14] it is suggested that “unless some discipline of the military kind were introduced” (in the event of nationalisation), “there would be no available methods of dealing with a national strike of railwaymen, other than to concede to their demands.” The question of “Strikes” has already been dealt with above (page 36). As to the political difficulty, although it is true that the number of Civil servants would be greatly increased (and it has been estimated that the total number of postal and railway servants who would have the vote might be as many as 600,000), it must be remembered, as pointed out by Mr. Emil Davies, that this number is spread over the whole Country, and the percentages in each district, compared to the whole number of voters, would not be a large one, except in railway centres like Crewe, where they already have a preponderance of votes. In any case, the same considerations which, as above mentioned, would be likely to prevent strikes, would operate equally in the region of politics if the four rules mentioned are adhered to, especially under the proposed scheme, carried on with the primary object of the public benefit. Exactly the same conditions would obtain as with the Post Office now. Other grounds of objection to State ownership are:-- =1. The fear of inefficiency owing to lack of competition.= =2. The fear of difficulty in obtaining redress for loss or injury from a Government Department.= =3. The fear of officialism.= =As to competition=, it is now generally admitted that there is no effective competition on railways.[15] In most parts of the country there never has been any competition, as one company only is available. In others, where more than one company operates, working arrangements have been made not only as to the fares and rates but also as to time of trains, thus precluding any effective competition. In the very nature of things no competition can be effective in a system of railway transit. As to the questions of =officialism= and =difficulties of obtaining redress=, can anyone suggest that these are less in the case of private companies, responsible to no one but themselves, than in the case of a Government Department with a Cabinet Minister at the head who is responsible to Parliament? A vote of censure is one of the most powerful weapons in Constitutional countries against any serious abuse in a Government Department. Mr. Edwin A. Pratt, in his book before referred to, cannot but admit the cogency of the argument in favour of the amalgamation and unification of the railways, but urges that this should be accomplished by the amalgamation of the whole of the existing railways into =a Trust or Traffic Board=. The answer to this is that when once constituted, even though appointed by Parliament, such a Board =is responsible to no one but itself=, and, however eminent may be the directors or managers, the want of ultimate responsibility inevitably and unconsciously leads to abuses. =Can any instance be adduced of the successful working of any such large Trust or Board?= On the other hand, instances are well known to the contrary. One of these was the notorious Metropolitan Board of Works. And is it certain that the Metropolitan Water Board and the Port of London Authority, both of which are constituted on similar lines, will answer all the expectations which were formed of them? There are, of course, difficulties inherent in the administration of a great Government Department, but, as already hinted, various remedies may be suggested for many of these difficulties. For instance, there might be elected =a Railway Council= or Standing Committee in Parliament, consisting of representatives of several large districts of the United Kingdom, and of which the “Minister of Transport” would be, ex-officio, the President. In the first instance possibly some of the present directors of railway companies, many of whom are already in Parliament, could be members of this Council. Any proposals for improvements, extensions or alterations in the services of the railway or Post Office would be submitted to and decided upon by this Council or Committee, subject to an appeal to Parliament on questions of principle or finance. This would be one means of obviating an objection found in some countries where the railways are owned by the State, namely, the continual trivial complaints made in Parliament about the railways. A further suggestion is that a =special Railway Court= should be established in London with branches in every important centre, and presided over by competent arbitrators to determine and adjudicate upon claims against the Department for personal injuries to passengers and servants, or for loss of or damage to goods, or by reason of delay, any one accident, involving a large number of claims, being dealt with by the same Court instead of being, as now, the subject of innumerable actions at law in the ordinary Courts. This Railway Court might also be useful in settling disputes between the Government and the men. OTHER OBJECTIONS. Apart from the objection to State ownership there are no doubt many who are now deriving income from railways who will fear that their interests may be prejudiced by the proposed change. Fortunately =there can be but very few who will be thus prejudiced=. As to the existing staffs, such as booking clerks and the Railway Clearing House staff, whose services would no longer be required in those particular departments, there ought to be more than sufficient vacancies for these in other but more necessary branches of the railway service, especially in view of the increased traffic which is sure to arise. =Many traders= who may at first sight consider that their profits would suffer if the scheme is adopted =will find= on further consideration =that the benefits= they will have by the proposed scheme =will be greater= than any loss they could possibly sustain. To take one instance. =Newspaper proprietors= may consider that upon railways being nationalised they would lose the benefit of the extensive and remunerative advertisements they now receive from competing railway companies. So far from there being any loss, there will be profits, partly by the official announcements which the Department will cause to be inserted in all newspapers of time tables, rates, etc., but even more so by the enormous saving in the carriage of paper and of the newspapers, in travelling expenses of special correspondents and others, and by the additional profits arising from increased circulation which is sure to follow upon the increased facility and cheapness of distribution. Mr. W. M. Acworth, the well-known railway expert, to whom I submitted a rough draft of this pamphlet, was kind enough, while refraining from any detailed criticism, to call my attention to what he considered a difficulty in my proposals. He says: “The fundamental objection to a scheme of average fares and rates is that people whose fares and goods rates are ‘averaged up’ will, so far as possible, cease to use the trains; those whose fares and rates are ‘averaged down’ will increase enormously, with a corresponding increase in working expenses. Have you appreciated that under your scheme a passenger from London to Glasgow would, in fact, in most cases pay, not 1s., but 3d. or 4d., by taking local tickets from London to Birmingham, Birmingham to Crewe, etc?” And he instances the Hungarian zone system, which has completely broken down, as a case in point. My answer to this is, first, that according to my scheme there is no “averaging up;” the flat fares are all “averaged down” to the minimum. Secondly, while welcoming the admission that the effect of “averaging down” is to increase the traffic “enormously,” I am sure that Mr. Acworth himself does not mean that the working expenses will increase in anything like the same proportion. He has himself pointed out in an article on railways[16] that the train cost of carrying 200 passengers and 10 passengers is practically the same. Further reasons for this fact are given under the heading of “Working Expenses” in this pamphlet. Thirdly, while admitting that under my scheme a passenger might, by taking three local trains which stop at all stations travel from London to Glasgow for 3d., I can hardly imagine that any but the smallest percentage of travellers would endeavour to save 9d. by taking a journey in which they would spend sixteen hours and have two changes at least, instead of travelling the same distance by one train, in eight hours, for 1s. As to the zone system, the whole advantage of the flat rate or uniform fare is lost by the difficulty of passing from one zone to the other. FOOTNOTES [6] “On Municipal and National Trading” by The Rt. Hon. Lord Avebury. Published by Macmillan & Co., 1907. Price 2/6. [7] “The Case Against Railway Nationalisation” by Edwin A. Pratt. Published by Collins, 1913. Price 1/-. [8] “On Municipal and National Trading,” pp. 56-92. [9] While this pamphlet has been in the Press, there has been a strike of the Leeds Municipal workers, and the threat of a strike in the Post Office. It will be interesting to see whether the considerations above mentioned under existing conditions will be borne out, and still more if when the causes are ascertained, it can be proved that had the principles here advocated been carried out in practice, there would have been no strike, nor any threat of one. [10] On Municipal and National Trading, p. 109. [11] Ibid, Chapter VII. [12] On Municipal and National Trading, p. 107. [13] “On Municipal and National Trading,” page 10. [14] “Westminster Gazette” of December 2nd, 1913. [15] See “The Railways of Great Britain” by Lord Monkswell. (Smith, Elder & Co., 1913. Price 6/-). A most interesting book, published since this pamphlet was written.--Lord Monkswell is not an advocate of nationalisation, but apparently has an open mind.--He admits that England is now only served by five groups of railways, and that there is no effective competition. [16] In Palgrave’s “Encyclopædia of Political Economy,” Vol. III. (1899), Article on Railways, signed W.M.A. CHAPTER V. FINANCE OF THE SCHEME. The final and most important criticism of the scheme will be on the matter of finance. The question is, can a sufficient revenue be obtained from the small uniform fares and rates proposed, after providing for working expenses, to pay not only interest on the purchase money but the purchase money itself? It is a curious coincidence that in the year 1838, before Penny Postage was instituted, the average amount received for every chargeable letter was 7d. and a fraction--the actual average railway fare now paid by every passenger (excluding season tickets). The number of letters carried during the first complete year after the uniform rate of 1d. was adopted was more than doubled. Notwithstanding this the deficiency in net revenue was about £2,000,000, and the deficiency was made good out of general revenue, this being well worth while owing to the great benefit to the nation of Penny Postage. In the case of railways, however, the amount involved is so large that no Government could be expected to give any consideration to a proposal which would involve making good so large a deficiency as would be occasioned by the reduction to a flat rate of 1d. As will be gathered from the remarks made when dealing with the principles of the scheme, this difficulty is now overcome by dividing the traffic on railways, both of passengers and goods, into two kinds of service, namely, Fast and Slow. It will be found that by this means =no greater percentages of increase of traffic will be required to produce the same gross revenue as at present than 15 per cent. of passenger traffic and 10 per cent. of goods traffic=. It will also be shown that if the increase of traffic should not exceed this estimate the additional working expenses will be so small that they would be more than met by the economies effected by unification. If these propositions prove to be true, then there will be no deficiency to be provided for. It is necessary in order to prove this to set out the figures of the present receipts and expenses, and an estimate of the same under the proposed new scheme. PRESENT FIGURES. The following are in round sums the average figures for the two years 1911 and 1912, based on the Railway Returns published by the Board of Trade annually under the Regulations of Railways Act, 1871:-- =(_a_) Passenger traffic receipts.= Season ticket holders £5,000,000 Other passengers 40,000,000 ----------- Total from passengers only 45,000,000 Mails and goods by passenger trains 10,000,000 ----------- Total from passenger traffic 55,000,000 =(_b_) Goods traffic receipts.= Minerals £30,000,000 General merchandise 32,500,000 Livestock 1,500,000 ----------- 64,000,000 =(_c_) Miscellaneous receipts.= Steamboats, docks, etc. 5,000,000 Hotels, rents, etc. 5,000,000 ----------- 10,000,000 ----------- Grand Total £129,000,000 =Expenditure.= Maintenance of ways, works, stations, docks, etc. 18,000,000 Traffic expenses 23,000,000 Locomotive and rolling stock expenses 28,000,000 General charges, rates and taxes 12,000,000 ----------- 81,000,000 ----------- =Net receipts= £48,000,000 =========== =Total number of passenger journeys=, including season ticket holders (assuming that each annual ticket represents 200 double journeys per annum only), about 1,620,000,000 Of this total there were first or second class passengers about 160,000,000 That is, about 10% of the total number carried. =The average fare for every journey is therefore 6½d.= In other words, if every passenger paid for every single journey, long or short, the sum of 6½d., then the gross receipts from passengers would be about the same amount as is now received. =Total tonnage of goods= per goods train: Minerals Tons 410,000,000 The receipts as above for these represent =an average of 1/6 per ton.= General Merchandise Tons 114,000,000 The receipts for these as above represent =an average of 6/- per ton.= ----------- Total tonnage per Goods Train Tons 524,000,000 =========== The total receipts for the two kinds of merchandise together =show an average of 2s. 4d. per ton.= Note that the total tonnage of minerals carried is about four times that of general merchandise. The total tonnage may be less than the above, owing to overlapping of the various companies, but for the purpose of my estimates I am taking these official figures. ESTIMATES UNDER PROPOSED SCHEME. (_a_) As to passenger traffic. There is, of course, no official return as to the proportions of Main line and Local passenger traffic, but it is clear that the percentage of small fares must be very great. Assume that this is over 80 per cent., then there would be in round figures about 300,000,000 (that is under 20 per cent.) of Main line passenger journeys, and assuming that the number of first class passengers will be only 10 per cent. (the above average percentage of first and second class passengers), then the revenue from the existing number of passengers under the new scheme would be as follows:-- =Main Line= 300,000,000 at 1/- equals £15,000,000 of whom 30,000,000 at an additional 4/- for First Class equals 6,000,000 =Local= 1,320,000,000 at 1d. equals 5,500,000 of whom 132,000,000 at an additional 5d. for First Class equals 2,750,000 ----------- ----------- =Present No.= 1,620,000,000 will produce £29,250,000 =========== as against the present total of £45,000,000, or a deficiency of about £16,000,000 per annum, assuming there should be no increase in the existing traffic. This seems an appalling deficiency, but “Wait and See!” It is quite clear that there would be a very large increase of traffic, more particularly of the long distance or Main line passengers, as under the existing system the fares for short distances up to 12 or even 20 miles are sufficiently low to remove practically all restrictions. In the case of long distances, however, there is this double restriction for passengers--namely, the time occupied and the high price of the fares. If the latter restriction is removed a very large increase of traffic is sure to result, not only for purposes of pleasure but also for business and trade purposes. The Local traffic will also increase partly by reason of the increased number of long distance passengers requiring the use of the Local lines (both suburban and small branch lines), and partly by the reduction to 1d. of many of the present suburban fares. In order, however, to be on the safe side in the estimate, I propose to take no account of any increase in Local passengers and to reckon only the increase required in the number of Main line passenger journeys. It will then be found that 250,000,000 more Main line passengers will provide for the above large yearly deficiency, as follows:-- 250,000,000 at 1/- £12,500,000 Add 25,000,000 at 4/- for First Class 5,000,000 ----------- £17,500,000 =========== This will bring the gross receipts from passengers to £46,750,000, with =an increase of about 15 per cent. only= on the present total number of passengers carried, and £1,750,000 more revenue. The criticism may be made, however, that this number is nearly double the existing number of long distance passengers. Will such an increase be realised? From a consideration of the following reasons it is submitted that not only will it be so, but that in point of fact a much larger increase may reasonably be anticipated. 1. No account as to passenger traffic has been taken of the normal increase in the number of passengers which has continued to increase regularly with the increase of population. 2. Under the proposed scheme the uniform fares are for _as far as the train travels only_, so that a journey say from London to Londonderry will involve at least three 1s. tickets, one to Holyhead, a second from Holyhead to Dublin, and a third from Dublin to Londonderry, whereas under the present system one through ticket would be purchased and would appear in the official returns as one journey only. 3. In practice nearly every single journey undertaken means _a return journey home_, so that an increase of 250,000,000 more passenger journeys does not involve a greater increase in the movement of the population than is represented by, say, 150,000,000 passengers. 4. If the number of passengers carried by the railways is compared with the population it may be noted that the total number of passengers carried last year in the Tube and Suburban Railways of London, with a population of between six and seven millions, was about 500,000,000 in addition to about the same number carried by omnibuses, and a further similar number by tramways. A similar proportion of railway passengers to the population of the United Kingdom of nearly 50 millions would be over 4,000,000,000 per annum, so that an actual total of 1,850,000,000 would undoubtedly be much less than may reasonably be anticipated. 5. It is not only the increased number of people who would travel to and from all parts of the country who now cannot or will not do so on account of the expense, but also the increase in the number of journeys undertaken by existing travellers. Parents living in remote parts of the country whose children work in large towns and who, on account of high fares, cannot visit each other, business men and commercial travellers who will multiply their long distance journeys for business purposes if they can do for 2s. what now costs 10 or 20 times as much, are a few among many classes who will swell the number. It will be remembered that by far the greater proportion of the population are those in receipt of an income of less than £3 per week to whom any fares of 10s. or over are prohibitive except in extreme cases. Let me give one very homely illustration which has come under my notice. A domestic servant in London had a serious illness, necessitating an operation at one of the hospitals. Her parents lived in humble circumstances in a Cornish village. The mother came to London and had to pay £2 for a return ticket. Her daughter had to remain about two months in the hospital while the mother had to return home without being able to afford the luxury of another return journey to London. But during the whole of that time trains were going to and from the same place every day and night with plenty of room for the old lady, who could, of course, have been carried any number of times without any appreciable cost to the company. Now, suppose the uniform fare of 1s. each way had come into operation, she or some other member of the family would, no doubt, have come up at least once a week, and instead of one return ticket which cost £2, and would be included in the Board of Trade returns as two passenger journeys, the family would have only paid 16s. for the eight double journeys, the extra cost to the Government would be nil and the increase in the number of passenger journeys would be 14. It is not unusual to see long distance trains arrive in London with not more than 15 or 20 passengers. (_b_) As to goods traffic. For the purposes of the estimates of goods traffic there must be added to existing total receipts from goods train traffic the amount included in the official returns under the head of “passenger traffic” of £10,000,000 received for mails, luggage, and other goods carried by passenger trains, making the total revenue for goods at present of £74,000,000. There is no official Return as to the tonnage of goods carried by passenger trains, but assuming that the present average rate for goods carried by passenger trains is £2 per ton, this would represent a further tonnage, irrespective of passengers’ luggage, of 20,000,000 tons. The figures under the new scheme, if there should be no increase in the tonnage carried, and assuming that goods by fast service should be no more than the amount now estimated per passenger train, would thus be as follows:-- By slow service 524,000,000 tons at 1/6 £39,300,000 By fast service 20,000,000 ” ” 10/- 10,000,000 Live Stock, as now 1,500,000 ----------- £50,800,000 Thus showing a deficiency of about 23,200,000 ----------- as against the present total of £74,000,000 =========== Following the analogy of the passenger traffic, I will only estimate for an increased traffic by fast trains, and for this purpose there will be required:-- 48,000,000 tons, which at 10s. equals £24,000,000, and will bring the total to £800,000 more than the present total receipts from goods, by both passenger and goods trains. This increased tonnage it will be seen is =an increase of under 10 per cent.= on the present total of 550,000,000 tons. It is probable that with a reduction of freight per fast train to the uniform rate of 10s. per ton, a considerable proportion of existing goods train traffic would be transferred to fast trains, so that the same figure might be arrived at with much less increase in tonnage. This fact may also be taken into account when adjusting any mistake in the official figures of the total tonnage carried. As in the case of passenger traffic, this percentage is surely not only a reasonable estimate, but one which may reasonably be anticipated, and, further, the increase will be progressive. The following among other reasons may be adduced:-- 1. The =example of the Post Office= is the best precedent that can be given of the result of the adoption of a minimum uniform rate. In the year before the introduction of Penny Post the number of letters per head of population was only three. This number is now 72, irrespective of postcards and parcels, and it is still increasing. The number of letters carried in 1838 was 70,000,000. In the first complete year after the Penny Post was established this number was doubled. In 1863 it had multiplied by eight times, and since then it has been doubled in about every period of 20 years. 2. The large amount of =goods sent now by road=, especially in recent years by motors and steam tractors on account not only of the heavy railway rates but also the cost of loading and unloading, would with uniform rates be sent by rail. In this connection it may be mentioned that a very considerable increase of carriage by trolley trucks of loaded carts and pantechnicons, or of the “containers” advocated by the New Transport Company, Limited, thus avoiding both shunting and the double expense of packing and unpacking, may reasonably be anticipated. 3. A still greater increase in fast train traffic may be expected in =perishable articles=, such as fruit, fish, milk and dairy produce. The so-called reduced rates now in force for instance for carriage of fresh fruit vary from 1s. 6d. per cwt. (equals £1 10s. per ton), from Hampshire to London up to as much as 8s. per cwt. (equals £8 per ton), from Hampshire to Scotland, these rates being “reduced” on account of the large amount of fruit (strawberries), requiring in the season special trains carrying nothing but fruit. The rates for the same goods from other parts where the quantity is not so considerable are in some cases more than double, so that the farmers cannot afford to send the goods. The rates for fish are similar, and the same considerations apply, so that very little is consigned to town except from fishing centres like Grimsby where large quantities are available. 4. =With a regular service= from every station, village stations as well as the large towns, and =similar to the present postal service=, in fact forming an extension to all goods of the present Parcels Post service, no one can doubt that the total increase will be considerably more than the 10 per cent. estimated for. CHAPTER VI. WORKING EXPENSES. Most critics will contend that the increased traffic will lead to an enormous increase of working expenses. In the first place allowance must be made for the several economies in management occasioned by the amalgamation of the whole railway systems in one and with the Post Office as already mentioned, and of which the following is a brief list, viz.:-- Abolition of, (_a_) The Clearing House, (_b_) Separate boards of directors and clerical staffs, (_c_) Legal and Parliamentary expenses, (_d_) Advertisements, (_e_) Book-keeping, printing and booking clerks now required for differential fares and rates. Economies by avoiding, (_a_) Competing Receiving Offices, Post Offices or stations in same localities, (_b_) Competing trains, (_c_) The waste of rolling stock now occasioned by the ownership of different companies, instead of being used according to the requirements of traffic. The latter has already been referred to in Chapter II. A further proof of a practical nature was given by Mr. Oliver Bury, the retiring General Manager of the Great Northern Railway in 1912, who then said that after the working arrangement with the Great Central Railway had been entered into, although there had been an increase of 4,000,000 tons of merchandise carried, this additional traffic had actually been worked with a decrease in the goods train mileage of 1,000,000. Apart from all these economies, =the working expenses cannot increase proportionately with the increase of traffic=. Most of the long distance passenger trains now running, except on special occasions or holiday time, could easily hold twice the number of passengers with but little, if any, appreciable increase in the cost of haulage. It must be remembered that a sufficiently powerful locomotive and sufficient coal must be provided for every passenger train, on the assumption that it will be full, whether it leaves with a full complement of passengers or not. Therefore, even though the number of passengers now carried were to be doubled in the case of all Main line trains very little increase in the working expenses would result, certainly not so much as the saving effected by the various economies mentioned. So far as goods traffic is concerned, an increase of 10 per cent. only, as estimated in the tonnage would certainly not cause any great increase in the expenditure. If, on the other hand, the increase of traffic should be very much more than the percentages mentioned (as may very likely be the case), then the revenue derived will be more than sufficient to provide whatever additional working expenses there may be. The expenses of the important items (which constitute probably 50 per cent. of working expenses) of permanent ways, stations, signal boxes, and general establishment charges would not be seriously affected by increase of traffic, only the rolling stock, coal, and part of the staff. In addition to these economies, and others set out more fully in Chapter II., there will also be great economy in the working expenses of the Post Office itself, including the telegraph and telephone services. The actual effect of the amalgamation of the two services of railways and Post Office on the total working expenses of the combined services cannot be estimated with any degree of accuracy, but there can be no doubt that it will result in large economies. The working expenses of both, must, of course, be lumped together. No advantage can possibly be gained by attempting to separate the expenses of various branches of one State Department. This has actually been attempted in the case of the telegraph service, one of the numerous branches of the Post Office. It has been continually asserted that this service has been, and is being, carried on at a loss, especially since the introduction of the sixpenny rate. This assertion has always been an enigma to me, for how any proper apportionment of the working expenses of over 20,000 Post Offices throughout the United Kingdom can be made, in order to ascertain what proportion is to be attributed to the telegraph service alone, passes comprehension! That this impossible task has been attempted, and apparently carried out to the satisfaction of some persons in authority, does not prove that the alleged loss has actually been made, but only that a large amount of time and expense has been lost in elaborate and costly calculations, which can be of no possible advantage to the service or the Country! It is to be hoped that this attempt will not be continued with the telephone service. If, and when, the scheme proposed in this pamphlet for combining railways with the General Post Office is carried into effect, I trust that no such expensive and useless task will be attempted as to endeavour to ascertain what proportions respectively of the expenses of running the Royal Railways are to be attributed to carrying His Majesty’s Mails on the one hand, or His Majesty’s subjects and their goods on the other! It is quite evident that on the two services being combined a portion of the present working expenses of the Post Office, namely, those which now consist of amounts paid to the Railway Companies for carriage of mails, for rents of telegraph and telephone wires, and other services rendered, will be swallowed up in the general working expenses, just as the gross receipts of the Post Office will swell the total revenue of the combined services. For the purposes, however, of ascertaining what increase of traffic will be required to produce (_a_) the same net revenue as under the present system of railways, and (_b_) a sufficient revenue to purchase the present system, I have taken no account of the decrease of Postal expenses nor of the normal increase of the Postal Revenue. I also am assuming that notwithstanding all the economies referred to, the working expenses of railways will remain the same, or even increase, owing to higher prices of goods and materials and higher wages, to the round sum of £85,000,000. It will thus be apparent that ample margin has been allowed for any increase in working expenses that is likely to take place, and that allowance has been made for the whole of the existing staffs to be retained, whether now employed in services which may then be discarded or not. P.S.--While revising the final proofs of this pamphlet during the Christmas Holidays, I have noticed in the “Daily Telegraph,” of 24th December, 1913, a long letter signed “G.P.O.,” referring to an article in the same well-known newspaper of the previous day. The letter is printed in prominent type under the following heading:-- “PREHISTORIC METHODS OF POST OFFICE FINANCE--TELEGRAPH SERVICE ‘LOSS.’” The correspondent, who evidently has expert knowledge of the subject, refers to the “alleged great loss” of the telegraph service as “a polite fiction.” His letter completely confirms the views expressed above as to the folly of attempting to apportion expenses of one branch of the service, and he places the cost of the accounts at “hundreds of thousands of pounds a year!” CHAPTER VII. TERMS OF PURCHASE. If the railway system be purchased by the nation it will be in contemplation as =a business proposition= to repay the capital expended in the purchase, and this means, therefore, that if this scheme is a practicable one =the shareholders and stockholders of the present companies will be able to receive back their capital=, although, under existing conditions, this appears absolutely hopeless. It is therefore now proposed to consider upon what terms the railways can be purchased and how the purchase money can be provided. 1. By the Railway Act of 1844 the Government is empowered to purchase every railway company formed after that date. The price fixed is the equivalent of 25 years’ purchase of the average annual divisible profits for three years before such purchase, subject to the proviso that any company whose divisible profits are less than 10 per cent. on its capital is at liberty to have the terms of purchase fixed by arbitration. At the date of this Act most of the Trunk lines, to the extent of about 2,300 miles had already been constructed and are not therefore subject to the provisions of this Act, but as the total length of lines open in 1911 was 23,417 miles, it will be observed that the Act applies to 90 per cent. of the whole railway system. Notwithstanding this, there are undoubted difficulties in estimating the actual purchase price, having regard to the fact that the majority of the smaller companies, including the modern Tube Railways with their large prospective profits, and probably the whole of the Irish railways, pay less than 10 per cent. and would, therefore, be entitled to arbitration. There is, however, another precedent, viz., (2) The Indian State Railways, which have been actually purchased by the Government from the private companies by whom they were owned. The dates and terms of purchase of these railways are included in an official return of railways acquired by the Government. This return was issued by the Board of Trade in 1908, pursuant to an order of the House of Commons.[17] In India the railway undertakings of 16 separate companies were acquired by the State between the years 1868 and 1906. Of these companies six were purchased at a price mutually agreed upon between the Government and the companies, these being small companies, and the purchase moneys varying from £30,000 to £300,000. Three companies were acquired at a purchase price equal to the share capital. The remaining seven companies were purchased for a sum equal to the value of the shares calculated at the mean market price during the three years preceding the date on which notice of purchase was given. In addition to payment of the purchase price the Government assumed the liabilities of the company in respect of debentures and debenture stock. Four of these companies (the larger ones) were, under an option reserved by the contracts, paid by annuities spread over 73 or 74 years. One of these, the East Indian Company, was purchased in 1879 at the price, calculated on the above basis, of £32,750,000, payable by an annuity of £1,473,750 for the term of 73 years from 1880. This amounts exactly to 4¼ per cent. on the purchase money, and will cease to be payable after the year 1953. In addition to this annuity, interest is paid on the debentures and loans amounting altogether to about £16,500,000, the interest whereon is about £500,000 or a little over 3 per cent. If the Act of 1844 were now applicable to the whole of the companies in the United Kingdom, and if we assume that by the time when the option to purchase is exercised the net profits of £48,000,000 in 1911 shall have risen to £50,000,000, the purchase money would be 25 times that sum, viz., £1,250,000,000. This sum is really slightly more than the total paid-up capital of the railways after allowing for “watered” stock. The following were the figures in 1911:-- Ordinary Stock £493,484,151 Preference and Guaranteed Stock 473,073,163 Loans and Debentures 357,461,047 ------------ =Total paid-up Capital= £1,324,018,361 ============== There is included in this total, stock to the nominal value of £198,000,000, or approximately 15 per cent., which represents nominal additions made on consolidations and divisions of stock, and commonly known as “watered” stock. It will be noticed that the present net revenue of £48,000,000 only represents an average of about 3½ per cent. on this total paid-up capital. The total paid-up capital in the returns recently published for 1912 is £1,334,963,518. The Railway Nationalisation Society has prepared heads of a Bill in Parliament, providing that the price to be paid for the whole of the railways shall be calculated on the basis of the Act of 1844. No doubt this would be opposed by holders of railway stocks and shares, having regard to the fact that the result might be in effect to merely return the capital, no account being taken of profits. If the purchase of the railways is to be considered as “a business proposition” it will be necessary to look fairly at both sides of the question, and endeavour if possible to arrange terms which will not prove an injustice to the present owners, and at the same time will be such as can be provided for out of the ordinary revenue of the railways without financial loss to the nation. It must be remembered that shareholders or their predecessors invested their money with the reasonable and proper expectation of having an adequate return for it. No doubt they put down their capital with the primary, possibly the sole, object of benefiting themselves, but the fact remains that their capital has been the means of providing the splendid net-work of British Railways now available for the nation to purchase. On the other hand, railway stock and shareholders must recognise that their position under the present system is by no means an enviable one. Many of them have for years been in receipt of no dividend whatever. In no case has there been any attempt at repayment of capital moneys, nor does there seem any prospect of it. The average net annual receipts now earned by the whole of the companies is only a fraction over 3½ per cent., and this percentage (which is less than before the year 1870) has for the last few years been practically stationary. The working expenses have been increasing to such an extent by reason of the increase of wages and price of materials that last year the companies decided on an all-round increase in fares and rates. According to the latest returns this has already been to a large extent counteracted by a decrease in traffic. If, therefore, an offer were made by the Government to purchase the whole of the railways upon similar terms to those on which the East Indian Railway was acquired, namely for a sum equal to the mean market price of the shares during the three years preceding the year in which the Act to acquire the railways is introduced, it is submitted that there could be no effective opposition to the proposal. In effect this would mean a purchase at a price which is the value the public to-day put upon each line of railway. The only practical difficulty of this proposal will be to ascertain the market value of the shares of some of the smaller companies, many of which are held by the larger companies. In order, however, to avoid under-estimating the amount required, I suggest for the purposes of my argument that the Government and the companies mutually agree on a total sum of £1,350,000,000 as the purchase price of all the undertakings of the companies, subject to the existing liabilities for loans and debenture stock, now amounting to £357,500,000, which would be assumed by the Government. This would make a total in round figures of £1,700,000,000, or nearly £400,000,000 more than the total of the ordinary preference and guaranteed stock. Surely this would be an outside figure. Indeed, it might be suggested that the nation would be paying an excessive amount. Mr. E. A. Pratt gives various estimates of what the purchase price would probably be.[18] These vary from £1,052,000,000 up to £1,769,847,000, an estimate of “The Railway News,” confirmed by the “Financier and Bullionist,” of September 7th, 1912. “The Financial News” in 1912 suggested £1,941,865,000 in 2½ per cent. Stock in order to yield the present annual income of £48,546,000. Taking the precedent of the East Indian Railway as a mode of payment and without making any allowance for better terms of interest which the Imperial Government might well obtain, it will be seen that the annual amount required to provide a purchase money of £1,350,000,000 and meet the above liabilities would be as follows:-- Annuities at the rate of:-- 4¼ per cent. on £1,350,000,000 £57,375,000 Interest at 3 per cent. on Debentures of £360,000,000 10,800,000 ----------- Total £68,175,000 =========== According to the estimates set out in Chapter V. (if no further increase of traffic is secured than is required for producing the present revenue), there would be available toward this annual sum required for purchase the following:-- Passengers 46,750,000 Goods 74,800,000 Miscellaneous, as now 10,000,000 ------------ Total £131,550,000 Deduct for working expenses, as above 85,000,000 ------------ Net revenue £46,550,000 This shows a deficiency to be made good of 21,625,000 ------------ In order to make up the annual sum of £68,175,000 ============ This annual amount could be provided by the following further increase in passenger and goods traffic respectively, viz.:-- 100,000,000 passengers at 1/- £5,000,000 10,000,000 ” ” 4/- 2,000,000 30,000,000 tons ” 10/- 15,000,000 ---------- Total £22,000,000 ========== In these estimates no account has been taken of the increased revenue of the Post Office, nor the increase in Local passengers and slow goods traffic respectively, which is sure to be realised, and the receipts for which would probably cover any increase in working expenditure. It will be noticed that if the above increase should be obtained the total estimated increase of passengers over the present totals would be as follows:-- Passengers 350,000,000 or about 21% Goods 78,000,000 or about 15% It is, of course, not essential to the success of the scheme that the whole of the increase here estimated should be obtained in the first year after nationalisation has been carried out, although it is considered that even in that short period, according to all precedents, so small a percentage of profits may fairly be anticipated. It would probably be necessary for the Government to raise a temporary loan for initiating the scheme, but in any case it appears essential that the purchase of the whole of the existing undertakings of the United Kingdom should be completed as =at one and the same date=. Other advocates of railway nationalisation suggest that the purchase should be carried out gradually, and this course has been followed by other nations. It is, however, of the very essence of the scheme here proposed that every part of the country shall have the benefit of the uniform fares and rates, and this would be impracticable unless the whole system be taken over by the Government at one time. The proposal that the price should be fixed by taking the mean price of stocks for the three years preceding the year in which the Act should be passed, is in order to avoid the market changes which might be caused by anticipation of purchase by the State. It is suggested that whatever price is taken as the basis of the purchase money, such price should include everything, so that the whole undertaking would be taken over without the necessity for any valuation of stock and plant, a prolific cause of so much trouble and expense, as in the case of the purchase of the National Telephone Company. It may be said that the figures of the railway systems are so vast that it would be impracticable to cope with them in one transaction. Enormous as the figures must necessarily be, the principle is exactly the same as in other financial transactions. Just as the Government acquired the undertaking of the National Telephone Company by purchase, which took effect on one day, so can this much larger transaction, or series of transactions, be carried out. It is assumed that the existing shares and stocks of railway companies would be converted into Government Stock, all necessary apportionments being made up to a date to be named in the Act of Parliament authorising the acquisition of the railways. Upon such date the completion of the whole transaction will be deemed to be effected. FOOTNOTES [17] This was on the initiation of Mr. Chiozza Money, M.P. [18] In “The Case against Nationalisation,” page 186. CHAPTER VIII. CONCLUSION. All reforms meet with opposition, mainly from persons whose interests may be prejudiced by the proposed change--also in many cases by experts. As to the latter, one remembers the story of the expert who, when the first proposal was made to cross the Atlantic by steam, wrote a pamphlet conclusively proving, to his own satisfaction, that it was a scientific impossibility to construct a steamer capable of carrying sufficient coal to do the journey! One of the first steamers to cross the Atlantic carried a consignment of such pamphlets! As to the former, as has already been pointed out in considering objections to the scheme, there is but a very small section whose interests need be prejudiced. Even those few who might suffer loss by the reform will recognise that the increased facilities of transport, with accompanying decrease of expense, will inevitably result in a great increase in and expansion of trade, by reason of the opening up of markets which have hitherto been practically inaccessible. Nor is there any reason why this opening up of new markets should be confined to the United Kingdom, for if other nations find that a system of small uniform fares and rates is not only practicable but remunerative here, they will surely follow our example, as in the case of Penny Postage, and the day will not be far distant, after the system has once been adopted in this country, when it will be possible to travel all over Europe at the cost of a few shillings, and to transmit and receive goods at correspondingly low rates. It is impossible to foresee all the social and political as well as financial effects which may be produced by such a revolution. The advantages of travel, which have hitherto been restricted to the wealthy, will be thrown open to all, whatever their means. Another important result may be anticipated and hoped for, namely, that the intermingling of the people of the various races and nations will tend to remove the prejudices, misconceptions and misrepresentations which have so often produced disastrous wars in the past. Should this be so, it may be that the reform here proposed will bring nations nearer to the desired haven of Peace. _A QUESTION for to-day and to-morrow_ The Case for LAND NATIONALISATION BY JOSEPH HYDER (_Secretary to the Land Nationalisation Society_). It deals with every aspect of the land question in a thorough and comprehensive manner. Full of facts, figures and cases which every land reformer ought to know. It gives numerous illustrations of the abuses which spring from treating land as private property. =2s. 6d. net.= End of the Project Gutenberg EBook of Royal Railways with Uniform Rates, by Whately C. Arnold *** END OF THIS PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK ROYAL RAILWAYS WITH UNIFORM RATES *** ***** This file should be named 53222-0.txt or 53222-0.zip ***** This and all associated files of various formats will be found in: http://www.gutenberg.org/5/3/2/2/53222/ Produced by MWS, Adrian Mastronardi, The Philatelic Digital Library Project at http://www.tpdlp.net and the Online Distributed Proofreading Team at http://www.pgdp.net (This file was produced from images generously made available by The Internet Archive/American Libraries.) Updated editions will replace the previous one--the old editions will be renamed. Creating the works from print editions not protected by U.S. copyright law means that no one owns a United States copyright in these works, so the Foundation (and you!) can copy and distribute it in the United States without permission and without paying copyright royalties. Special rules, set forth in the General Terms of Use part of this license, apply to copying and distributing Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works to protect the PROJECT GUTENBERG-tm concept and trademark. Project Gutenberg is a registered trademark, and may not be used if you charge for the eBooks, unless you receive specific permission. If you do not charge anything for copies of this eBook, complying with the rules is very easy. You may use this eBook for nearly any purpose such as creation of derivative works, reports, performances and research. They may be modified and printed and given away--you may do practically ANYTHING in the United States with eBooks not protected by U.S. copyright law. Redistribution is subject to the trademark license, especially commercial redistribution. START: FULL LICENSE THE FULL PROJECT GUTENBERG LICENSE PLEASE READ THIS BEFORE YOU DISTRIBUTE OR USE THIS WORK To protect the Project Gutenberg-tm mission of promoting the free distribution of electronic works, by using or distributing this work (or any other work associated in any way with the phrase "Project Gutenberg"), you agree to comply with all the terms of the Full Project Gutenberg-tm License available with this file or online at www.gutenberg.org/license. Section 1. General Terms of Use and Redistributing Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works 1.A. By reading or using any part of this Project Gutenberg-tm electronic work, you indicate that you have read, understand, agree to and accept all the terms of this license and intellectual property (trademark/copyright) agreement. If you do not agree to abide by all the terms of this agreement, you must cease using and return or destroy all copies of Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works in your possession. If you paid a fee for obtaining a copy of or access to a Project Gutenberg-tm electronic work and you do not agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement, you may obtain a refund from the person or entity to whom you paid the fee as set forth in paragraph 1.E.8. 1.B. "Project Gutenberg" is a registered trademark. It may only be used on or associated in any way with an electronic work by people who agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement. There are a few things that you can do with most Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works even without complying with the full terms of this agreement. See paragraph 1.C below. There are a lot of things you can do with Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works if you follow the terms of this agreement and help preserve free future access to Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works. See paragraph 1.E below. 1.C. The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation ("the Foundation" or PGLAF), owns a compilation copyright in the collection of Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works. Nearly all the individual works in the collection are in the public domain in the United States. If an individual work is unprotected by copyright law in the United States and you are located in the United States, we do not claim a right to prevent you from copying, distributing, performing, displaying or creating derivative works based on the work as long as all references to Project Gutenberg are removed. Of course, we hope that you will support the Project Gutenberg-tm mission of promoting free access to electronic works by freely sharing Project Gutenberg-tm works in compliance with the terms of this agreement for keeping the Project Gutenberg-tm name associated with the work. You can easily comply with the terms of this agreement by keeping this work in the same format with its attached full Project Gutenberg-tm License when you share it without charge with others. 1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside the United States, check the laws of your country in addition to the terms of this agreement before downloading, copying, displaying, performing, distributing or creating derivative works based on this work or any other Project Gutenberg-tm work. The Foundation makes no representations concerning the copyright status of any work in any country outside the United States. 1.E. Unless you have removed all references to Project Gutenberg: 1.E.1. The following sentence, with active links to, or other immediate access to, the full Project Gutenberg-tm License must appear prominently whenever any copy of a Project Gutenberg-tm work (any work on which the phrase "Project Gutenberg" appears, or with which the phrase "Project Gutenberg" is associated) is accessed, displayed, performed, viewed, copied or distributed: This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License included with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you are not located in the United States, you'll have to check the laws of the country where you are located before using this ebook. 1.E.2. If an individual Project Gutenberg-tm electronic work is derived from texts not protected by U.S. copyright law (does not contain a notice indicating that it is posted with permission of the copyright holder), the work can be copied and distributed to anyone in the United States without paying any fees or charges. If you are redistributing or providing access to a work with the phrase "Project Gutenberg" associated with or appearing on the work, you must comply either with the requirements of paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 or obtain permission for the use of the work and the Project Gutenberg-tm trademark as set forth in paragraphs 1.E.8 or 1.E.9. 1.E.3. If an individual Project Gutenberg-tm electronic work is posted with the permission of the copyright holder, your use and distribution must comply with both paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 and any additional terms imposed by the copyright holder. Additional terms will be linked to the Project Gutenberg-tm License for all works posted with the permission of the copyright holder found at the beginning of this work. 1.E.4. Do not unlink or detach or remove the full Project Gutenberg-tm License terms from this work, or any files containing a part of this work or any other work associated with Project Gutenberg-tm. 1.E.5. Do not copy, display, perform, distribute or redistribute this electronic work, or any part of this electronic work, without prominently displaying the sentence set forth in paragraph 1.E.1 with active links or immediate access to the full terms of the Project Gutenberg-tm License. 1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary, compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form, including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you provide access to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg-tm work in a format other than "Plain Vanilla ASCII" or other format used in the official version posted on the official Project Gutenberg-tm web site (www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or expense to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or a means of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original "Plain Vanilla ASCII" or other form. Any alternate format must include the full Project Gutenberg-tm License as specified in paragraph 1.E.1. 1.E.7. Do not charge a fee for access to, viewing, displaying, performing, copying or distributing any Project Gutenberg-tm works unless you comply with paragraph 1.E.8 or 1.E.9. 1.E.8. You may charge a reasonable fee for copies of or providing access to or distributing Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works provided that * You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive from the use of Project Gutenberg-tm works calculated using the method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg-tm trademark, but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, "Information about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation." * You provide a full refund of any money paid by a user who notifies you in writing (or by e-mail) within 30 days of receipt that s/he does not agree to the terms of the full Project Gutenberg-tm License. You must require such a user to return or destroy all copies of the works possessed in a physical medium and discontinue all use of and all access to other copies of Project Gutenberg-tm works. * You provide, in accordance with paragraph 1.F.3, a full refund of any money paid for a work or a replacement copy, if a defect in the electronic work is discovered and reported to you within 90 days of receipt of the work. * You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free distribution of Project Gutenberg-tm works. 1.E.9. If you wish to charge a fee or distribute a Project Gutenberg-tm electronic work or group of works on different terms than are set forth in this agreement, you must obtain permission in writing from both the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation and The Project Gutenberg Trademark LLC, the owner of the Project Gutenberg-tm trademark. Contact the Foundation as set forth in Section 3 below. 1.F. 1.F.1. Project Gutenberg volunteers and employees expend considerable effort to identify, do copyright research on, transcribe and proofread works not protected by U.S. copyright law in creating the Project Gutenberg-tm collection. Despite these efforts, Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works, and the medium on which they may be stored, may contain "Defects," such as, but not limited to, incomplete, inaccurate or corrupt data, transcription errors, a copyright or other intellectual property infringement, a defective or damaged disk or other medium, a computer virus, or computer codes that damage or cannot be read by your equipment. 1.F.2. LIMITED WARRANTY, DISCLAIMER OF DAMAGES - Except for the "Right of Replacement or Refund" described in paragraph 1.F.3, the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the owner of the Project Gutenberg-tm trademark, and any other party distributing a Project Gutenberg-tm electronic work under this agreement, disclaim all liability to you for damages, costs and expenses, including legal fees. YOU AGREE THAT YOU HAVE NO REMEDIES FOR NEGLIGENCE, STRICT LIABILITY, BREACH OF WARRANTY OR BREACH OF CONTRACT EXCEPT THOSE PROVIDED IN PARAGRAPH 1.F.3. YOU AGREE THAT THE FOUNDATION, THE TRADEMARK OWNER, AND ANY DISTRIBUTOR UNDER THIS AGREEMENT WILL NOT BE LIABLE TO YOU FOR ACTUAL, DIRECT, INDIRECT, CONSEQUENTIAL, PUNITIVE OR INCIDENTAL DAMAGES EVEN IF YOU GIVE NOTICE OF THE POSSIBILITY OF SUCH DAMAGE. 1.F.3. LIMITED RIGHT OF REPLACEMENT OR REFUND - If you discover a defect in this electronic work within 90 days of receiving it, you can receive a refund of the money (if any) you paid for it by sending a written explanation to the person you received the work from. If you received the work on a physical medium, you must return the medium with your written explanation. The person or entity that provided you with the defective work may elect to provide a replacement copy in lieu of a refund. If you received the work electronically, the person or entity providing it to you may choose to give you a second opportunity to receive the work electronically in lieu of a refund. If the second copy is also defective, you may demand a refund in writing without further opportunities to fix the problem. 1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth in paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you 'AS-IS', WITH NO OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED, INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE. 1.F.5. Some states do not allow disclaimers of certain implied warranties or the exclusion or limitation of certain types of damages. If any disclaimer or limitation set forth in this agreement violates the law of the state applicable to this agreement, the agreement shall be interpreted to make the maximum disclaimer or limitation permitted by the applicable state law. The invalidity or unenforceability of any provision of this agreement shall not void the remaining provisions. 1.F.6. INDEMNITY - You agree to indemnify and hold the Foundation, the trademark owner, any agent or employee of the Foundation, anyone providing copies of Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works in accordance with this agreement, and any volunteers associated with the production, promotion and distribution of Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works, harmless from all liability, costs and expenses, including legal fees, that arise directly or indirectly from any of the following which you do or cause to occur: (a) distribution of this or any Project Gutenberg-tm work, (b) alteration, modification, or additions or deletions to any Project Gutenberg-tm work, and (c) any Defect you cause. Section 2. Information about the Mission of Project Gutenberg-tm Project Gutenberg-tm is synonymous with the free distribution of electronic works in formats readable by the widest variety of computers including obsolete, old, middle-aged and new computers. It exists because of the efforts of hundreds of volunteers and donations from people in all walks of life. Volunteers and financial support to provide volunteers with the assistance they need are critical to reaching Project Gutenberg-tm's goals and ensuring that the Project Gutenberg-tm collection will remain freely available for generations to come. In 2001, the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation was created to provide a secure and permanent future for Project Gutenberg-tm and future generations. To learn more about the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation and how your efforts and donations can help, see Sections 3 and 4 and the Foundation information page at www.gutenberg.org Section 3. Information about the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation is a non profit 501(c)(3) educational corporation organized under the laws of the state of Mississippi and granted tax exempt status by the Internal Revenue Service. The Foundation's EIN or federal tax identification number is 64-6221541. Contributions to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation are tax deductible to the full extent permitted by U.S. federal laws and your state's laws. The Foundation's principal office is in Fairbanks, Alaska, with the mailing address: PO Box 750175, Fairbanks, AK 99775, but its volunteers and employees are scattered throughout numerous locations. Its business office is located at 809 North 1500 West, Salt Lake City, UT 84116, (801) 596-1887. Email contact links and up to date contact information can be found at the Foundation's web site and official page at www.gutenberg.org/contact For additional contact information: Dr. Gregory B. Newby Chief Executive and Director gbnewby@pglaf.org Section 4. Information about Donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation Project Gutenberg-tm depends upon and cannot survive without wide spread public support and donations to carry out its mission of increasing the number of public domain and licensed works that can be freely distributed in machine readable form accessible by the widest array of equipment including outdated equipment. Many small donations ($1 to $5,000) are particularly important to maintaining tax exempt status with the IRS. The Foundation is committed to complying with the laws regulating charities and charitable donations in all 50 states of the United States. Compliance requirements are not uniform and it takes a considerable effort, much paperwork and many fees to meet and keep up with these requirements. We do not solicit donations in locations where we have not received written confirmation of compliance. To SEND DONATIONS or determine the status of compliance for any particular state visit www.gutenberg.org/donate While we cannot and do not solicit contributions from states where we have not met the solicitation requirements, we know of no prohibition against accepting unsolicited donations from donors in such states who approach us with offers to donate. International donations are gratefully accepted, but we cannot make any statements concerning tax treatment of donations received from outside the United States. U.S. laws alone swamp our small staff. Please check the Project Gutenberg Web pages for current donation methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of other ways including checks, online payments and credit card donations. To donate, please visit: www.gutenberg.org/donate Section 5. General Information About Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works. Professor Michael S. Hart was the originator of the Project Gutenberg-tm concept of a library of electronic works that could be freely shared with anyone. For forty years, he produced and distributed Project Gutenberg-tm eBooks with only a loose network of volunteer support. Project Gutenberg-tm eBooks are often created from several printed editions, all of which are confirmed as not protected by copyright in the U.S. unless a copyright notice is included. Thus, we do not necessarily keep eBooks in compliance with any particular paper edition. Most people start at our Web site which has the main PG search facility: www.gutenberg.org This Web site includes information about Project Gutenberg-tm, including how to make donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, how to help produce our new eBooks, and how to subscribe to our email newsletter to hear about new eBooks.